Americas

Puerto Rico

  • Puerto Rico
    Could Maria’s Legacy Be a New Debt Trap for Puerto Rico?
    President Trump is right to worry that disaster aid will end up bailing out the holders of Puerto Rico's bonds, but there are better solutions to that particular problem than cutting off disaster aid to Puerto Rico.
  • Puerto Rico
    Will the Proposed Restructuring of COFINA Bonds Assure Puerto Rico’s Return to Debt Sustainability?
    Puerto Rico’s government and the bulk of the holders of Puerto Rico’s Sales tax backed bonds (COFINA) appear to have reached agreement on restructuring terms (details here). The deal will reduce Puerto Rico’s near-term payments, freeing up a bit more money to support Puerto Rico’s reconstruction. But the terms, in my view, still fall short of providing Puerto Rico with a clear path back to debt sustainability.    This is largely because the payments on the restructured bonds rise over time—while Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay may fall over time. It isn’t clear what will support Puerto Rico’s economy once the $80 billion or so from federal disaster relief funds and private insurance payments run out.    The rise in payments on the sales tax backed bonds might be justified if Puerto Rico was paying back the bond’s principal—and thus reducing its debt stock over time (and freeing up borrowing capacity to finance new investment).   But that isn’t what is happening—or rather, it isn’t exactly what is happening. Technically Puerto Rico will be paying back the principal on some of the new sales tax backed bonds it plans to issue—but those payments will be offset by the growing amount Puerto Rico owes on a second bond (a capital appreciation bond) that is lurking in the background. When the $9.6 billion in new sales tax backed bonds issued in the restructuring are paid off, Puerto Rico will still owe….$14.2 billion on its sales tax backed bonds (Exhibit A, see p. 130 of the .pdf). It isn’t hard to think of alternative deal terms that wouldn’t leave creditors that much worse off but that would substantially reduce the long-run risks to Puerto Rico. I hope it is not too late for those alternatives to receive serious consideration.  The COFINA Restructuring   The old sales tax backed (COFINA) bonds in many ways posed the greatest long-term risks to Puerto Rico’s debt sustainability, even though they account for roughly a third of Puerto Rico's tax-supported debt.* Because of the diabolical structure of the capital appreciation bonds, the real burden of the COFINA bonds was actually a lot higher than implied by the $17.5 billion in bonds outstanding in 2017 ($11.5 billion in current interest bonds, $6 billion in capital appreciation bonds).** Puerto Rico faced an increase in debt service over time from around $700 million back to $1.8 billion. And since the bonds had a direct claim on 5.5 percentage points of Puerto Rico’s sales tax revenue, rising debt service would effectively starve the government of funds. So what happened in the restructuring (outlined in exhibit A, p. 130 and appendix B, p. 140)? About $11.5 billion in current interest bonds, with a coupon of almost 6 percent (current interest payments are around $700m), will be swapped into $9.6 billion of new bonds with an average coupon of 4.5 percent. There is some real debt relief in this deal—payments on COFINA bonds fall from the current level in the near term, freeing up funds for the budget. But creditors are also trading up in a couple of important ways. The old bonds were a mix of senior and junior bonds. The new bonds are all senior bonds. The debt reduction (not surprisingly) is coming from the junior bonds, which get equal status with the senior bonds.  The payment structure on the current interest bonds is also being pulled forward—they are all paid off over the next twenty-five years. Payments on the capital appreciation bonds were moved back.  1Accreted value of the CABs is misleading, as payments were pushed back, providing more time for the bonds to grow in value 2See this link. And by reducing the size of the maximum annual payment from $1.8 billion to $1 billion the bond holders substantially increased the strength of the sales tax pledge.   There is an easy way to see this—under the terms of the COFINA deal, the bondholders get first dibs on a 5.5 percentage point sales tax, up to a certain defined amount (the pledged sales tax base). The sales tax now raises close to $250 million per percentage point—so 5.5 percent raises something like $1.5 billion. If that tax didn’t grow over time, well, the bond holders would be in trouble, as under the old payment schedule Puerto Rico has to pay a peak of $1.85 billion or so. By reducing the peak payment, the bondholders made it much less likely that the 5.5 percent sales tax will not generate enough revenue to cover the payments.****  A stronger pledge is worth a lot, particularly for the junior bonds. So in practice the bond holders aren’t giving up quite as much as it seems. They get less cash, but the quality of their security interest has substantially improved. If the deal only consisted of the current interest bond, it basically would work—$500m or so of interest is something that Puerto Rico likely can afford, even taking into account that it will need to pay something on its other bonds. What creates the trouble? Pulling forward the amortizations of the current interest bond, and filling the backend with a new capital appreciation bond. The current $6 billion in capital appreciation bonds are being swapped into a new $2.4 billion capital appreciation bond. But don’t focus too much on the current notional value—capital appreciation bonds (CABs) don’t pay a coupon, so their current value doesn’t represent a current payment burden. They cause problems because they grow in value over time and thus lurk in the background as a threat to long-term debt sustainability. Since the new CAB doesn’t start making payouts until 2044, it also has longer to quietly accrete (to use the technical term of the increase in the value of the bond). At its peak, it rises to $14.2 billion in value, before it is paid off over about fifteen years (in a series of $1 billion a year installments—it really is structured as a series of zeros, technically speaking, though not for tax purposes). That’s less than the old capital appreciation bonds, but still too much. The risk of the new bond, as I see it, is that the amount Puerto Rico needs to pay will double (from under $500 million to $1 billion) over the next twenty years before leveling off (exhibit 3, p. 10). And that rise in payments does not help to reduce Puerto Rico’s outstanding debt stock. With a capital appreciation bond hiding in the background, the amortization payments on the current interest bond are in a deep sense fake, as the capital appreciation bond is growing in value faster than the current interest bonds are being paid off. The increase in payments would be fine if Puerto Rico’s economy could reasonably be expected to double over the same period. That’s the case when for example an emerging economy has just experienced a big depreciation, raising the current value of its foreign currency debt—but also creating a dynamic where the currency should recover in real terms over time. But it isn’t a sure bet for Puerto Rico.   The oversight board is projecting that Maria, and the influx of disaster aid that followed, will in effect jolt Puerto Rico out of its post 2006 torpor. The risk, of course, is that Puerto Rico’s economy fades once the influx of federal disaster funds (estimated to reach close to $10 billion a year at its peak, providing —counting a modest multiplier—something like a $2 billion plus boost to Puerto Rico’s economy; see exhibit 9, p. 20) goes away.   Think of it this way: right now, Puerto Rico isn’t paying the bulk of its debt and it is receiving large sums of federal disaster funding (including $4.8 billion in additional Medicaid funding). In the future, Puerto Rico will need to pay the new debt that emerges out of the restructuring and it won’t benefit from the disaster funding. The next five years should be fine. The five years that follow might not be. What’s frustrating to me is that there are fairly obvious alternative payment structures on the new sales tax backed bonds that would leave Puerto Rico in a much more sustainable position.   Take one simple alternative: replacing the new capital appreciation bond with an equivalent amount of current interest bonds for example, and amortizing these bonds over 40 years.   Increasing the amount of current interest bonds would raise the interest payment on the new bonds to $540 million—above the level in the proposed deal, but below what Puerto Rico pays now. And in a pure amortizing structure (discounted at 4.5 percent) Puerto Rico would need to pay a flat $650 million a year—but that would be enough to pay the bond off entirely over forty years (and cut its value by a third over twenty years). That is less than Puerto Rico now pays into the COFINA trust, and far less that it has to pay in the future under the proposed new structure. And it is the kind of deal that is robust against the most obvious risk that Puerto Rico faces, namely that it falls back into long-term stagnation, with a high rate of out-migration limiting its future economic size (and debt servicing capacity). And it provides a clear path back to the kind of debt load that would be consistent with eventual statehood as well. Creditors wouldn’t be that much worse off in this structure—they get a bit more cash up front.   The negotiations over COFINA were heavily driven by the terms of the legal settlement over the sales tax pledge—together with the governor and the board’s still fairly optimistic assumptions about long-run growth. No one seems to have imposed a strong debt sustainability overlay on the new deal. If the governor really wants to have a realistic path to statehood, he needs to make sure Puerto Rico’s isn’t out of line with that of the more indebted states—but the call here ultimately rests with the board, which needs to certify that the restructuring is done on terms consistent with Puerto Rico’s long-term sustainability. Assessing Overall Debt Sustainability That leads to the most important, and most difficult, question: what would a sustainable debt payments profile for Puerto Rico look like? Right now, the debt sustainability analysis in Puerto Rico’s latest fiscal plan—and in the COFINA fiscal plan—is thin. The COFINA debt sustainability analysis essentially just showed that the projected sales tax pledge covers the bond's projected payments, with no analysis of how the pledge would impact Puerto Rico’s overall finances if sales tax revenue doesn’t grow as projected and no clear assessment of how much would be left over for other creditor groups. To assess Puerto Rico's debt sustainability, I think it helps to lay out two strong presumptions to help simplify a complicated debate. The first is that Puerto Rico’s sustainability shouldn’t hinge on an assumption that Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay will rise over time. The payment profile on the debt consequently should be fairly flat—unless the payment on a portion of the debt is contingent on growth and truly poses no burden if Puerto Rico’s economy stalls when disaster relief funds run out. The second is that Puerto Rico should be aiming to keep overall payments relative to tax revenues on its tax supported debt in line with that of the fifty states (particularly after 2022, when disaster aid falls off and Puerto Rico has to stand on its own two feet).    Let’s go through the argument for both.*** Why should the board assume that Puerto Rico’s payment capacity won’t rise substantially over time? After all, economies do normally grow, at least in nominal terms. 1. Puerto Rico’s economy was shrinking before Maria. One lesson the IMF has learned painfully over time is that assuming that past trends don’t reassert themselves is dangerous. The available studies on the long-term effects of natural disasters also aren’t encouraging. 2. Demographics aren’t going to work in Puerto Rico’s favor. Even without further out-migration, Puerto Rico’s population will shrink (the board forecasts it will fall from 3.4 million pre-Maria to about 3 million in 2022, and further falls are a given as a result of a low birth rate and past out-migration). And so long as workers can earn more—and get more federal benefits—in Orlando than San Juan, a certain fraction of the rising cohort of new Puerto Ricans will move off-island. A natural decline in the working age population of around 1 percent a year could easily turn to 2 percent.  3. Federal aid falls off a cliff in five years. The $4.8 billion in extra Medicaid funding actually expires earlier, but the governor and board now expect other federal aid disbursements to ramp up as the Medicaid funds fade. The sharp fall off in overall help is now projected to start after fiscal 2022—and the fall off in funding then is steep (p. 20 of the fiscal plan). The board’s forecasts, I think, assume that the fall off in Federal disaster funding isn’t a permanent shock to growth and output. That’s too optimistic in my view. The significant rebound in tax collections that followed the most recent influx in federal aid won’t last forever, so the fall in federal funds also directly impacts the budget.****    4. Puerto Rico’s economy still relies heavily on pharmaceutical manufacturing, and the long-term commitment of the pharmaceutical sector to Puerto Rico isn’t clear after the new tax reform. Puerto Rico’s government also relies heavily on taxes on the pharmaceutical sector and a large software firm that once upon a time produced floppy disks in Puerto Rico—companies that are often in Puerto Rico more for tax reasons than because they really need to be in Puerto Rico. The current tax reform—and the future tax reforms needed to fix the holes in the current tax reform—pose a risk to Puerto Rico. 5. The gains from structural reform are uncertain. There is no doubt that Puerto Rico has room to improve the efficiency of government services, and to make it easier to do business on island. Projecting those reforms will raise the level of output by a couple of percentage points over time is reasonable. But assuming that often painful reforms can offset the drag from the future loss of federal funds and permanently change Puerto Rico’s trend growth is a risk. They could. But if the gains are less than expected and don’t offset the demographic headwinds, Puerto Rico could be in real trouble.  Legally binding increases in payments worry me, as the payment increase is far more certain than the improvement in Puerto Rico’s capacity to pay. I consequently believe the growth baseline that the board uses to assess sustainability should be fairly conservative, with only modest assumed nominal GNP growth.  So much for the slope on the payment curve. What is a reasonable overall level of payments? This is all an art more than a science, but one key benchmark should be the level of debt service relative to Puerto Rico’s own revenues. The state average is around 4.5 percent. New York pays 8 percent. The most indebted states, on average, pay just over 9 percent (exhibit 20, p. 36). Puerto Rico’s revenues —using the board’s definition of the entities that make up the commonwealth, net of federal aid—are expected to rise to $15 billion over the next few years (Exhibits 13 and 14, pp. 25-26). Keeping Puerto Rico's debt service in line with the average state implies overall payments of close to $0.7 billion a year, keeping it in line with say New York would imply payments of $1.2 billion a year, and keeping it below the average of the most indebted states would imply holding payments under $1.4 billion a year. The high end of that range scares me. Benchmarking Puerto Rico against Massachusetts and Connecticut is risky. Poorer parts of the country likely have less capacity to support high levels of debt than rich states. And Puerto Rico's core tax revenues are actually well below total revenues. The commonwealth—focusing on the revenues that are central to the General Fund’s budget—historically has struggled to collect $10 billion in tax, even counting the tax revenues siphoned off in various revenue pledges that backed the debt that was designed to stay off the formal budget. Look at the fiscal 2018 numbers, which, to my surprise, benefited as much from post-Maria disaster aid than they were hurt by the immediate after effects of Maria.  Puerto Rico collected something like $2.5 billion in sales tax (counting funds that went into the COFINA trust for future debt service), around $2.0 billion in individual income tax,***** $1.5 to $2 billion in corporate income tax (an unusually high number thanks to disaster funding, see p. 27), $1 billion in gasoline and auto taxes (also an unusually high number), $0.5 billion in alcohol and tobacco taxes, and something like $0.25 from Puerto Rico’s share of the federal rum tax. To get tax revenue up to $10 billion, you need to include the roughly $2 billion Puerto Rico currently extracts out of the pharmaceutical and software sectors (thanks to Act 154 and non-resident withholdings). It is hard to get large amounts of tax revenue out of a poor population, and there are limits to Puerto Rico’s ability to use things like university fees to pay debt service. The “true” tax base of Puerto Rico is modest: Puerto Rico cannot rely on the continued willingness of the United States to in effect let Puerto Rico win in a game of tax competition.  For those sovereign analysts used to thinking of the level of debt service relative to GNP, $1.0 billion is roughly 1.5 percent of current GNP, $1.4 billion is about 2 percent of GNP and $2 billion is around 3 percent of GNP.  What’s the risk of pledging a large part of Puerto Rico’s tax base to future debt service (especially if all other debt benefits from a specific revenue pledge that is designed to be bankruptcy remote)?  Simple: A big gap between what Puerto Ricans pay in tax and what they receive in government services could mean more out-migration, as Puerto Ricans can avoid paying these taxes by moving to Florida. The negative impact of a large debt service burden though isn’t really in the board’s economic forecast, thanks to a host of very technical modelling assumptions (the board’s economic model assumes that fiscal consolidation only temporarily reduces output, so a bigger primary surplus has no impact on long-term growth; there is no hysteresis effect). The only way to make Puerto Rico sustainable then would be to have the federal government provide more help—as Puerto Rico’s taxes won’t be available to pay for essential government services. That starts to look a bit like the Federal bailout that Congress wanted to avoid. The sales tax backed debt accounts for just over a third of the tax supported bonded debt ($17 billion of $45 billion). The constitutional bonds have a similar share of the total debt (the Puerto Rico Building Authority (PBA) debt has constitutional status along with the listed GO debt). Holders of the constitutional debt will no doubt argue for a mirror image deal that would raise Puerto Rico’s debt service to $2 billion even if the more junior bonds get zero. That is substantially too high in my view: it would put Puerto Rico's debt service well above that of any state.    In other words, the COFINA deal, as currently structured, only works if other groups of creditors get relatively little. There is an enormous gap between the tone of the articles that have looked back at Maria a year on, and the optimistic forecasts that are embedded in the economic plans that are being used in the restructuring deals that Puerto Rico is negotiating with various groups of creditors. If Puerto Rico's growth disappoints, the proposed $1 billion in annual debt service on the sales tax backed bonds on its own would leave Puerto Rico with a higher debt service burden than an average U.S. state. That’s why I think it is important to keep the long-run payment commitment to COFINA under $700 million—and why I hope the alternative deal outlined here isn’t rejected as out of hand.   *Puerto Rico's tax supported debt can be broken into three broad buckets: the sales-tax backed bonds, the constitutional "GO" bonds (which have special protection under Puerto Rico's constitution and were in theory subject to a limit on their issuance) and the rest, a set of bonds that are either subject to clawback and thus junior to the "GOs" or that are explicitly junior. The likely junior claims include: the highway bonds ($4 billion), the pension obligation bonds ($3 billion), the rum bonds (PRIDCO, $2 billion), the conventions and UPR bonds ($1 billion) and the very junior bonds of the public finance corporate ($1 billion). The GDB’s estate also has over $2 billion in junior loans to the highways authority and other entities that I think remain outstanding. Pick your number on the recovery of this bucket… **The capital appreciation bonds have a near nuclear structure. They aren't consistently disclosed (Capital Appreciation Bonds: “are only shown in a footnote on the balance sheet of the issuer; it is not required that they be shown as a liability or expense since there are no current interest payments. This can serve to hide the future liability”), they raise almost no money when they are sold and they give rise to large future claims. The “headline” number for the size of the COFINA claim thus is a little deceptive. The real debt burden is higher. While the GOs posed the biggest short-term legal risk to Puerto Rico after a default (Puerto Rico owed about a $1 billion in principal and interest on the GOs, funds that might be pulled straight out of the budget), the rise in COFINA debt service from $0.7 billion a year (in 2015) to $1.8 billion a year (by 2040) was going to be a source of enormous pressure on Puerto Rico’s treasury.  ***Revenue from the 5.5 percent sales tax is projected to grow from $1.4 billion to over $2.5 billion over the next twenty years, assuring that there is enough to cover $1 billion in debt service. (exhibit 19, p. 30). That though isn’t an assessment of the risk to Puerto Rico’s sustainability of this pledge, as in bad states of the world Puerto Rico bears the downside (it gets less revenue out of the sales and uses tax, so a higher fraction ends up going to the pledge—there is no risk sharing). ****The fiscal plan makes clear that nearly every single tax line item has been influenced by the disaster funding. Corporate income tax receipts notably have increased because of payments from contractors who set up Puerto Rican subsidiaries. Debris removal uses a lot of gasoline, so gasoline tax revenues (clawed back from the Highway bonds) have soared. Insurance funds have led to a surge in car purchases, and thus auto tax revenues. As a result of these revenues, and the Medicaid funding, Puerto Rico didn’t experience the fall off in tax revenue that was initially feared, and didn’t need a Treasury/FEMA fiscal bridge loan. *****If Puerto Rico fully replicated the federal EITC in its tax code, its income tax revenue would fall to just around $1 billion. The absence of federal income tax on personal income earned in Puerto Rico isn't the boon that some argue, as the progressive structure of federal income tax implies the federal government would collect relatively little tax out of Puerto Rico.
  • Puerto Rico
    Looking Back on Fiscal 2018 as Puerto Rico Starts a New Fiscal Year
    Sales tax revenues have recovered. Fiscal year 2019, which started in July, should be a good year thanks to Federal disaster aid. The real question though is what happens when Federal aid starts to fall.
  • Puerto Rico
    The Oversight Board’s Latest Fiscal Plan for Puerto Rico is Still Too Optimistic
    The power is off in Puerto Rico, again. It may not be restored for a day or two. Puerto Rico obviously has yet to fully recover from Maria’s devastation. Tax revenues this fiscal year are off by over $800 million—or about 10 percent. Sales tax revenues are about 30 percent below forecast (pg. 7, line 3). The fall overstates the underlying fall in activity—as a group of bondholders (for now) has first claim on a portion of the sales tax (until the funds needed to cover payment on the bond are set aside). As a result, the risk of any shortfall in sales tax proceeds is born almost entirely by Puerto Rico’s Treasury. The impact of that pledge shows how Puerto Rico’s debt still complicates Puerto Rico’s recovery. Tax revenues for Puerto Rico’s fiscal year will be something like $1 billion less than forecast—perhaps a bit less than some feared immediately after Maria, but still a substantial shortfall. It is all, more or less, consistent with an economy expected to fall by a bit more than ten percentage points (in real terms) this year. And, well, in July, according to the new fiscal plan put forward by the Oversight board, a new round of fiscal austerity kicks in. Puerto Rico’s fiscal year runs from July to June. The proposed fiscal tightening “measures” are about a percentage point of GNP in fiscal 2019. The board expects this tightening to push down output (relative to baseline) by about 1.25 percent of GNP. Not all of the tightening in fiscal 2019 comes from spending cuts—about half the 2019 measures are designed to raise revenues. But in 2020 and 2021 the austerity really kicks in, with spending cuts (versus baseline) of well over a percentage point of GNP in both years (see exhibit 3 on p. 4). That austerity is needed in no small part because Puerto Rico is surviving for now off a one-off supplemental increase in Medical funding from the federal government that will run out in 2020. Before the hurricane, Puerto Rico’s economy was in structural decline—with output (and population) falling by at least a percentage point a year. And its tax favored medical manufacturing sector (Puerto Rico is outside of the United States for income tax purposes, so firms operating in Puerto Rico need not pay U.S. corporate income tax) will be a bit less tax favored after the tax reform,* so it faces a new structural headwind. It all is rather bleak. And it make the optimism about Puerto Rico’s near term economic path that is embedded in the latest fiscal plan put forward by the oversight board all the more risky. The board has essentially embraced Governor Rosello’s argument that Maria will prove to be a positive growth shock (see my Bloomberg View column with Antonio Weiss and Desmond Lachman). The board isn’t quite as rosy as the governor. But it basically gets close to Rosello’s forecast by 2023—it just gets there through explicitly forecasting very large gains from its proposed structural reforms in the last three years of its fiscal plan (see exhibit 6 on p. 9 of the proposed fiscal plan). The board’s forecast would put output about 10 percentage points above its forecast the in last year’s fiscal plan in 2023, and only just a bit below its pre-Maria level. And that comes even in the face of a quite strong fiscal consolidation. Larry Summers aptly described the associated risk: “Puerto Rico's oversight board will countenance too much debt service and too much austerity because of rosy scenario economics and excessive faith in structural reform.” Let me try to outline, best I can, the key assumptions behind the baseline growth numbers embedded in the oversight board’s fiscal plan. The board’s baseline—which has embedded in it an assumption about the impact of federal disaster relief aid—implies that the pace of underlying economic decline will slow a bit post-Maria. The no (further) fiscal consolidation, no structural economic reform baseline has output down about three percentage points from its pre-Maria levels in 2023. There is a 12-13 percent fall this year, and then solid recovery. This is a tad optimistic in my view. Remember that the underlying pace of decline was about a percentage point a year before Maria, and federal tax law is now at the margin less favorable to Puerto Rico. But there is no doubt that federal disaster spending will help. I am less concerned about the level than the path: federal disaster aid and private insurance funding is projected to decline from fiscal 2021 on, and it isn’t clear that this fall off is having much impact. The board forecasts that fiscal consolidation from fiscal 2019 on will knock about five percentage points off output (see exhibit 9 of the fiscal plan on p. 13; I applaud the board for making this transparent). If that was all that was in the board’s forecast, output in 2023 would be about eight points below its pre-Maria level—and not that far off from the level of output embedded in the previous fiscal plan. That’s realistic in my view: if an economy in decline has to do significant austerity, output is forced down. And Congress hasn’t made the fundamental policy choices that would be needed to allow Puerto Rico to avoid a new round of austerity. But with disaster spending falling (see exhibit 8) and ongoing austerity, the board is forecasting quite positive growth in fiscal 2021, 2022 and 202 That is because of the projected impact of structural reforms. They appear—based on the growth forecasts in the face of austerity—to be adding about two percentage points to growth in all three years. That seems quite high, given the nature of the reforms. I can see a modest impact from reforms even in an economy that is likely more demand than supply constrained—but would think that a cumulative increase in output (versus baseline) of two percentage points (e.g. a bit over 50 basis points year) would be on the optimistic side. I am suspicious that structural reforms will have a bigger impact than the austerity and fall-off in projected disaster spending (even if the impact of the infusion and then withdrawal of disaster spending on the local economy is modest thanks to a high level of imported content). Remember that before Maria trend growth was negative 1 percent per annum, so getting positive 2 percent growth in the face of austerity takes a really big assumed payoff from reform. (See the difference between the previous board forecast for growth in the out years in exhibit 91, p. 139). The strong projected increase in growth in fiscal 2021, 2022 and 2023 avoids any second round impacts of austerity: revenues go up, not down even with all the fiscal tightening thanks to the projected increase in nominal and real GNP. And that increase in revenue is strong enough to more than offset a forecasted fall in the revenue Puerto Rico is able to collect through a special tax that it now imposes on the “offshore” (for tax purposes) pharmaceutical manufacturing sector (I do give the board credit for forcing Puerto Rico to incorporate a fall in this revenue in its forecast—though in a sense the combination of Maria and tax reform has forced the board’s hand as Act 154 revenue is now falling). Exhibit 80 on p. 126 has the details of the fiscal side of the fiscal plan) As a result of these technical assumptions (big and fairly rapid payoff from structural labor market reforms that often are painful in the short-run, a quick payoff from reforms to an electrical system which unquestionably needs fundamental changes and no second round impacts of austerity) Puerto Rico is forecast to run a primary surplus of around 2 percent of GNP in 2023 ($1.4 billion) and sustain that kind of surplus for several years (see exhibit 20 and 21 on p. 27). That’s why the proposed fiscal plan shows more capacity to pay debt than before Maria—which is no doubt both the most politically salient and the most market relevant point.**   That forecast primary surplus is big enough—for a time—to allow Puerto Rico to pay the current coupon on the two groups of tax supported bonds that believe they have the strongest claim (the “constitutional” GOs and the sales tax backed “COFINA” bonds). The forecast primary surplus path thus seems to be at odds with the board’s debt sustainability analysis. It suggests Puerto Rico could sustain a higher level of debt than a typical state even though it is much poorer than a typical state. Remember, median household income in Puerto Rico is about ½ that of Alabama or Mississippi, and about 1/3 the level of the U.S. If nothing else, an implied debt level that would effectively preclude any realistic path to statehood should get a bit of attention from Governor Rosello. The real risk though is more fundamental. Forecasting a sustained boom (by Puerto Rican standards) after Maria means Puerto Rico may end up committing to an unrealistic level of debt service. And that would leave a debt overhang that blocks any sustained return to market access—and would make a second debt restructuring likely. Puerto Rico’s disastrous demographics only add to this risk. The board’s current forecast effectively assumes that Puerto Rico can grow even with a structural fall-off in federal support (as Puerto Rico loses federal medical funding eventually), a fall-off in disaster spending, a shrinking population, and a 2 percent of GNP gap between what Puerto Ricans pay in tax and what they get back in local spending (a burden that Puerto Ricans can escape should they migrate, as no state runs a comparable primary surplus). That seems too optimistic to me—the technical assumptions basically forecast away the downside risk. And I think that downside risk is substantial. A simple model that keeps trend growth unchanged and adds in the forecast impact from fiscal consolidation gives results similar to last year’s fiscal plan—e.g. another 10 percent or so fall in real GNP, which brings the cumulative fall in output from 2006 to close to 25 percent. There is another argument that may resonate with more international readers. The board’s technical assumptions from fiscal 2021 onward run contrary to many of the lessons the IMF thinks it learns from the eurozone crisis. The IMF put out a formal lesson learned paper (here’s the summary blog) in 2016 (based on work done in 2015, but formal publications have lags). The analogy is of course imperfect, as the eurozone’s fiscal and banking union differ from the American fiscal and banking union (as applied to the unique case of Puerto Rico). But Puerto Rico is like most eurozone member states an economic unit that has (some) fiscal autonomy (before its debt crisis) while lacking monetary autonomy. Three of the IMF’s lessons learned seem particularly relevant: Recovery inside a monetary union takes time. The oversight board has recognized this. It isn’t assuming that Puerto Rico is going to be able to access markets any time soon, all financing gaps are covered out of revenues (assuming the revenues materialize). Fiscal consolidation lowers output and often raises the debt burden in the short-run. It isn’t clear that this lesson has been internalized. The fiscal adjustment is offset in the first few years by disaster spending and then by projected payoff from structural reforms (that Puerto Rico is resisting)—growth is forecast to stay quite positive over the “program” period (e.g. through fiscal 2023). Unrealistically so in my view. “Painful” structural reforms are in fact “painful” and don’t yield a quick payoff—they cannot realistically offset the impact of fiscal austerity. This isn’t to say reforms don’t matter—Puerto Rico cannot continue as is, and fundamentally reforming the electrical grid, raising the standard for fiscal transparency, creating a mini-EITC, and ultimately bringing Puerto Rican labor law into closer alignment with U.S. labor law all strike me as necessary even if the labor market reform will be painful. But projecting a big short-term payoff from such reforms that fully offsets the drag from large scale austerity is dangerous—the available precedents suggests that such supply side reforms cannot offset the demand impact of fiscal consolidation.*** To be blunt, the board’s baseline runs the risk of repeating some of the IMF’s initial mistakes in Greece—though the drama may play out more slowly. In Greece the IMF initially made the mistake of thinking that Greece would be able to return to market borrowing quickly, and the mistake of predicting that massive austerity wouldn’t have a big negative impact on output. In Puerto Rico there is no assumption of a quick return to the markets, but there is an assumption that a period of fairly intense austerity won’t drag down growth. * The impact of the tax reform on Puerto Rico is complicated, but likely to be negative thanks to the BEAT, and the partial deductibility of foreign tax against the GITLI. Puerto Rico historically has been used to move profits on pharmaceutical and medical device sales out of the U.S.—it thus differs a bit structurally from tax havens that largely served to allow American firms to avoid paying U.S. tax on profits from their global sales. Consequently it is likely hit harder than some other tax centers by the “base erosion” measures that are designed to protect the integrity of a territorial system. ** The exact amount of debt that the primary surplus outlined in the fiscal plan can support can and should be debated. It would fall if the board insists on a standard amortizing structure, and insists that the available resources for debt service fall after 2028 (as is in their latest forecast). It also would fall if the board insists that debt payments reflect uncertainty about Puerto Rico’s ability to achieve the optimistic path laid out in the fiscal plan for the next ten years means that Puerto Rico can only commit a fraction of the forecast primary balance to cover contractually fixed debt payments (“the base bond” if there is both a base bond and a growth bond). The fiscal plan for the commonwealth now covers about $40 billion in bonds—as the Highway debt and the Government Development Bank (GDB) debt fall under separate fiscal plans (as of course does the debt of the main utilities PREPA and PRASA). $1.5 to $2b in forecast primary surplus from 2023 to 2028 thus comes reasonably close to covering most of the interest on these bonds. That is why I think it is at odds with the more modest levels of debt proposed in the debt sustainability analysis. Puerto Rico’s underlying level of tax revenue is actually quite modest—it gets $3.5 billion from personal and corporate income tax (a number that would fall to $2.5 billion if it matched the federal EITC), something like $2.5 billion from sales tax, and something like $1 billion from various taxes on crude oil, gasoline, cigarettes, and the like, so something like 10 percent of GNP in tax revenue out of Puerto Rico’s own economy (in no small part because Puerto Rico is poor, and thus the income tax yields less). Without the extra income it gets from the potentially footloose pharma sector, its underlying tax base is small—and I think that is at least relevant for thinking about its capacity to support a high primary surplus. *** I think there is a strong argument that Puerto Rico cannot achieve the sustained growth the oversight board forecasts without help from the U.S. Congress—it may not be able to do it on its own. Extending the federal EITC would have a tremendous long-run impact in my view—but it would require in effect agreeing to treat Puerto Rico better than a state, as it would get the “reward for low-paid work” now provided through the federal income tax code without paying federal income tax (e.g. all gain, no pain).  
  • Puerto Rico
    Counting Chickens Long Before They Hatch: Should Hurricane Maria Be Modeled as a Positive Growth Shock for Puerto Rico?
    Puerto Rico’s latest fiscal plan appears to use a best case scenario as its base case. It consequently doesn’t provide a realistic benchmark for evaluating Puerto Rico’s long-run capacity to pay.
  • Puerto Rico
    Repowering Puerto Rico with Solar a Worthwhile Goal, But Harder Than It Sounds
    In the wake of Hurricane Maria, there is an opportunity for Puerto Rico to reconstruct its energy infrastructure to be more resilient and efficient. However, if short-term rebuilding is prioritized over long-term restructuring, this critical window will be missed.
  • Puerto Rico
    Puerto Rico Update: PROMESA, Population Trends, Risks to the Fiscal and Economic Plan—and Now Maria
    A new report from the Center for International Governance Innovation (CIGI), co-authored by Brad W. Setser and Gregory Makoff.
  • Puerto Rico
    What Puerto Rico Tells Us About Global Trade
    Trade in tax often trumps trade in tasks.
  • Puerto Rico
    Puerto Rico Before Maria
    My new discussion paper with Greg Makoff on economic and demographic trends in Puerto Rico.