International Economic Policy

  • Economics
    Future of Tariffs and Trade
    Play
     Brad W. Setser, CFR’s Whitney Shepardson senior fellow, leads the conversation on the influence of tariffs on global trade and the price of U.S. goods, and what to expect from the second Trump administration’s economic policies. A question-and-answer session follow his opening remarks. TRANSCRIPT FASKIANOS: Welcome to the Council on Foreign Relations State and Local Officials Webinar. I am Irina Faskianos, vice president for the the National Program and Outreach here at CFR. CFR is an independent, non-partisan membership organization, think tank, and publisher focused on U.S. foreign policy. We are also the publisher of Foreign Affairs magazine. As always, CFR takes no institutional positions on elected officials, political candidates, or matters of policy. Through our State and Local Officials Initiative, CFR serves as a resource on international issues affecting the priorities and agendas of state and local governments by providing analysis on a wide range of policy topics. We’re delighted to have over 650 participants confirmed for today’s discussion from fifty-two states and U.S. territories. We appreciate your taking the time to be with us for this discussion. And I want to just remind you all that the webinar is on the record, the video and transcript will be posted on our website after the fact, at CFR.org. We are pleased to have Brad Setser with us to discuss the future of tariffs, trade, and U.S. economic policy. Brad Setser is the Whitney Shepardson senior fellow here at CFR. His expertise includes global trade and capital flows, financial crisis analysis, and the debt economy. From 2021 to 2022, he served as senior advisor to the United States Trade Representative. Prior to that, he was deputy assistant secretary for international economic analysis at the U.S. Treasury, from 2011 to 2015. He is the coauthor of the book, Bailouts or Bail-Ins?: Responding to Financial Crises in Emerging Economies. And he authors the blog on CFR.org entitled Follow the Money. So I hope you all sign up to receive those posts. So, Brad, thanks very much for being with us today for this conversation on the future of tariffs and global trade. We’ll have a conversation between us and then we’ll open it up to all of you for your comments, both written and raised hands. So maybe you could begin by giving us an overview of the purpose tariffs serve in trade and economic statecraft. SETSER: Well, I think you can argue that tariffs serve three broad purposes. The first purpose is to introduce a bit of friction. I mean a tariff is a tax imposed at the border that anyone who wants to import a good has to pay. And so it tends to raise the price of imports. So one use of tariffs is to protect a particular U.S. industry from foreign competition—be it all foreign competition or be it unfair foreign competition. So that's kind of the classic protective or insulating role of tariffs. The U.S. tariffs that were put on against steel, imported steel, when there was an excess of global supply of steel several years ago would be a good example. Another use of tariffs, which has sort of gone out of favor but President-elect Trump has alluded to quite often recently, is simply to raise revenue. Tariff is a tax. Taxes raise revenue. And so you could use the revenue generated by a broad across-the-board tariff to either close the fiscal deficit or offset other tax increases. That use of tariffs is not—has not been common in the postwar period, but that was probably the original use of tariffs back in the 1700s, 1800s, 1900s. Countries that didn’t have income taxes and had limited capacity to collect sales tax could control a port. And if you could control a port, you could put tariffs on goods coming through that port. The third use of tariffs is to provide leverage in a negotiation. Now, that leverage can be leverage that’s intended to open up other countries’ markets. That’s been the classic use. So if you think of a free trade agreement, it is an agreement whereby the U.S. would lower its normal baseline tariffs. In another country, a partner would also lower its tariffs so that there would be no tariffs on trade between those two countries. So you could generate leverage by negotiating over the terms through which you bring your tariffs down. President Trump, in his first term, revived the older idea of threatening to raise tariffs and saying that we’re going to raise tariffs, whether because you’re acting unfairly or because we don’t like the outcome of trade. And if you don’t make changes, we will go to higher and higher levels of tariffs. So that’s tariffs for leverage. Classically, tariffs have been used as leverage for trade goals, for commercial goals. A good example would be the Section 301 case against China that President Trump brought in his first term, which was resolved, at least partially, by a commitment by China to buy a lot more U.S. goods. So the threat of tariffs was used to extract commitments from your counterparty. Those different—and I guess I should add that, at least conceptually, you could use tariffs in the way we use sanctions. Sanctions are used not to generate economic or commercial outcomes but as leverage to pursue broader, more political goals. And you could, at least in principle—although it's an unusual use of tariffs—use tariffs to try to pursue those broader political goals. It is worth noting that these different goals are a bit in tension. If you want the tariffs to be protective, you may want a very high level of a tariff. A very high level of a tariff, though, doesn't generate any revenue. If there is no trade, there's no revenue. If you want the trade tariffs as a source of revenue, you can’t have many exclusions. You can’t tailor the tariff very much, because every exclusion loses significant amounts of revenue. The bigger—an initial exclusion becomes a big exclusion over time, because everyone reroutes trade to take advantage of that. So if you’re going to use tariffs as a source of revenue, they’re very—it’s very hard to actually use them also as a source of negotiating leverage. So in some sense, you have to choose between those different objectives. But they are all objectives that, at least in principle, can be pursued with a threat of tariffs. FASKIANOS: So what tariffs are currently in place on U.S. imports? Are they effective? And what do you see shifting come 2025? SETSER: Well, I concede that I do not have the capacity to read the mind of the President-elect. And I thought I had a reasonably good read on what he might be doing, but I certainly didn’t expect the first big tariff threats to be directed primarily against Canada. So I think a little bit of humility is required. So if you just look at the standard tariffs that the U.S. applies, MFN tariffs, or permanent trading relations tariffs, those tariffs average about 2 percent across all goods. The tariffs on China that were introduced in President Trump’s first term on average created a 15 percent additional tariff on trade with China. China was about 20 percent of U.S. trade. So that would have been about a three percentage point increase in the tariff level in overall terms. However, when you raise tariffs on one country, like China, and not on others, trade tends to reroute around those higher tariffs. So you didn’t actually see an increase in the overall effective tariff to 5 (percent). It’s probably more like 3 or 4 percent. Most of the trade that we still have with China is in those subcategories of trade that were left out of the tariffs in Trump’s first term, most significantly iPhones. You know, there’s another way of looking at tariffs. You can sort of say, if you divide trade into industrial goods and agricultural goods, agricultural goods generally have a certain amount of friction, a certain amount of tariffs, a certain amount of non-tariff barriers. So there’s generally not fully open trade. But for industrial goods, the norm is actually very open trade. Over half of all U.S. industrial trade is at a zero tariff, even if you don’t have a free trade agreement, and another quarter is at a very low tariff, not a prohibitive tariff. So if you look at it on a product category, we have significant tariffs in part around autos, 2 ½ percent for a normal car, but 25 percent for a light truck or a heavy SUV. We have significant tariffs around steel and aluminum and some metals. We have significant tariffs around some categories of clothing, apparel, where you can get around that tariff if you are in a free trade agreement with the U.S. and use U.S. yarn and fiber and fabric. And obviously, there are still important limits on certain parts of agricultural trade. But electronics, pharmaceuticals, a whole range of goods essentially are un-tariffed, even without a formal free trade agreement. I think, you know, President Trump has generally suggested if you listen to his campaign pledge, two broad types of changes. One is that he wants to raise tariffs on trade with China. He already raised tariffs on trade in China in his first term, raising them—you know, there were different tariff lists, one at 25 (percent), one at 7 ½ (percent), one at zero (percent). They averaged out to be at about a fifteen percentage-point increase in tariffs. There have been two possible evolutions suggested. One is to withdraw permanent trading relation status with China, which would raise the average tariff to somewhere between 40 and 45 percent. And then President-elect Trump has suggested possibly going to a 60 percent tariff on all Chinese goods. Now, he’s also suggested, and certainly, advisors have suggested, that this is a threat for negotiating purposes. It’s going to be a source of leverage. We may not end up with that high a level of tariff across the board on China. But that was certainly one big focus. The other big focus was the across-the-board tariff, 10 percent, sometimes it's been suggested a 20 percent tariff, on everything. That would be intended as a source of revenue, to allow a lower income tax. That takes—if you're going to use it to reduce income tax, that would have to be part of a budget package. And that would be a different use. It would be more of a revenue-raising use and less of a negotiating leverage use. And then finally, in the past couple of weeks, he's—President-elect Trump has threatened 25 percent tariffs on Canada and Mexico over immigration, over fentanyl, sometimes to needle "Governor" Trudeau, to use President Trump's phrase, and suggest that Canada might want to think about becoming the 51st state. I don’t think that’s a serious threat, but it is a somewhat unexpected threat. FASKIANOS: Mmm hmm. And it did—it did mean that Trudeau did go down to Mar-a-Lago to see President-elect Trump. So I think it probably did elicit a response. So the tariffs, what does it mean for the consumer? There’s been a lot of talk about the—what it will mean for the average American for these tariffs that President-elect Trump is talking about. SETSER: So, as I alluded to at the start, a tariff is a tax on imports. And that tax is paid, in the first instance, by the importer. Whoever is picking up the good at the port has to show they've paid the tax before they can take delivery of the goods. There's a debate about whether the exporter, knowing that the importer has to pay the tax, will adjust their prices down in a sort of share some of the burden of the higher tariff. The empirical evidence from the first round of tariffs on China was that that effect was very modest, that there was very limited falls in the price of goods imported from China. And so, thus, the importer more or less had to pay—you know, had to pay the tariff. And so a 20 percent tariff would lead to basically a 19 percent increase in the cost the importer—the total cost the importer faced on that good. There’s a second question, which is if the importer is a retailing company or a company that’s using the import as a good and as an input into its production, how much is passed on to the final consumer? And there have been different studies that come—sometimes find almost complete passthrough, and sometimes find that a significant share of the increase in cost is absorbed by the company that does the importer, not the final consumer. But I think—and then, you know, conceptually goods that compete with the tariffed good should also go up in price. So you could have a broader increase in price than just the increase in price on the good that faces the tariff. All that put together, I think it is generally reasonable to assume that if you raise tariffs on 10 percent of U.S. consumption, roughly imported goods by 10 percent, you’re probably going to have a 1 percent increase in the price level. And you’re probably going to get close to a 1 percent increase in federal government revenue. It gets more complicated if you push the tariffs up higher, and then you kind of—you force companies to find alternatives to just paying the tariff. But for modest tariffs, I think the simple linear math is generally pretty close to right. So a 10 percent across-the-board tariff is actually a pretty big—a pretty big increase in aggregate prices. FASKIANOS: And will that contribute to, you know, the inflation going—inflation going up? SETSER: I think that is a more complicated question. And it gets to how one defines inflation. Generally, economists think of inflation as an ongoing series of increases in the price level. So not just a one-off change. So if oil goes from fifty to a hundred, I think most people in—who are not economists, would say that’s very inflationary. And an economist would say, well, that’s just a jump in the price level. If it stays flat at a hundred, that’s not going to be any further increase in inflation. And the complexity comes from the fact that if the government is collecting a lot of tax revenue from the tariffs and that is reducing the deficit, that is taking money out of consumers’ pockets and they have less money to spend on other goods. So the aggregate impact of the increase in the tariff on inflation depends quite significantly on whether you offset that with other tax cuts. So my view is that you should view a tariff that is not offset with other tax cuts as a one-off increase in the cost of living, not as inflationary. And you should view—there’s some small inflationary effects from less efficient production. There’s some disinflationary effects because consumers have less money to spend on other goods. But basically, it’s just a—you feel poorer because you’re paying more for the same goods. If you offset with tax cuts, or if the Federal Reserve tries to offset with looser monetary policy, then you certainly run in the risk of what would be normally called inflation, ongoing increases in price levels. FASKIANOS: Great. So we’re going to go to the group for their questions, comments. We already have one written question, and I’ll look at the raised hands. So I’ll take the first written question from State Representative David Michel, from Stamford, Connecticut: Is this no tariffs not due to the allowance of quotas under President Biden that enables U.S. operations to buy steel, for example, to the limits where we are filling the gap between what we produce and what we need? And is anything going to change with European steel? SETSER: So with respect to Europe, Japan, Korea, and others, there were exclusions granted as part of a negotiated arrangement for imports of steel. So the overall tariff from the Section 232 trade action is 25 percent. But for defined quantities from specific countries there were tariff rate quotas, which let a certain amount of steel come in, typically the amount of steel that was imported historically from that country, without paying the tariff. This was meant to—well, it was not meant—it was part of a deal whereby Europe and others didn’t retaliate against the U.S. tariffs, which were imposed on them. They didn't accept, as a matter of principle, that the U.S. should have imposed the tariffs because they were done under a national security claim. And Europe says, you know, and Canada, we're your allies. We're not a national security threat. So as a sort of settlement, the Europeans and others were given tariff rate quotas up to a certain point. That agreement expires in the spring of 2025, so next year. If it expires, the tariff rate quota would go away. And then Europe would be free to impose its retaliatory tariffs on a range of U.S. goods, I think including whiskey. I forget exactly. I would hope that that agreement is extended. The Europeans would like it to be more flexible over time. They think that the—because the tariff rate quotas are for narrow products and for an individual country, in aggregate Europe hasn’t been able to get as much access to the U.S. steel market as expected. And so they would like it to be more liberal. The steel industry, I think, thinks that the regime for Mexico, in particular, but maybe Mexico and Canada, which is a separate deal, was too expansive, didn’t impose enough restrictions. And there was a general hope that we could move towards something that did more to support clean and green steel, less coal-based, blast furnace-based steel. More innovation and hydrogen-reduction steel. That doesn’t feel like it’s going to go anywhere under a Trump administration. So I actually don’t know the answer. My gut is, because, you know, unless you’re going to be very aggressive right off the bat and want to pick at an old scab, I would think it would make sense to find some agreement to extend the current arrangement. But if you want to initiate a more hostile negotiating environment with Europe, if you want to go after the Europeans, this deal does expire in the first part of next year. FASKIANOS: Thank you. I’m going to go next to Patty Alley, who’s a councilmember in South Kingstown, Rhode Island. You’re unmuted, so go ahead. OK, I think we’re having some technical difficulties. You’re muted again. OK, I’m sorry. Maybe you could type your question and we’ll take it in written, because we’re not hearing you. I’ll go next to Paul Brierley, with the Arizona Department of Agriculture, I believe. Q: Yeah, that’s correct. Paul Brierley with Arizona Department of Agriculture. It's been kind of my perception, anyway, that often when we impose tariffs on a country, they impose counter-tariffs on agricultural imports coming from our country to theirs. Could you just speak to that, what might happen there? SETSER: Well, it's more than your perception. That is, in general, how countries respond, particularly China, because China imports a lot of agricultural goods from the U.S. Why is that? Well, we're an agricultural exporter. And then also some of the agricultural states have significant senators. So when Mitch McConnell was the Senate majority leader, Kentucky Bourbon was on every tariff list imaginable. You know, it was just a way of putting on the Senate. When Paul Ryan was the speaker of the House, you would see a lot of retaliation against Wisconsin cheese and Harley-Davidson. You know, countries tend to go after prominent products from states that have significant leadership positions in the House and the Senate, to try to put reverse pressure back on the United States. With respect to China, and since President-elect Trump has threatened additional tariffs on China, China almost always retaliates against U.S. agriculture. Why? Well, in some sense it is easier for China to find alternative sources of agricultural supply than it is for China to find alternative sources of semiconductors, or aircraft, although they’re not buying very many aircraft right now. If you put tariffs on U.S. aircraft, and only the U.S. and the EU can supply large commercial aircraft—at least, you know, the Chinese C919 is only available in limited quantities—you’re effectively handing the market over to the European Union, to Airbus, and you’re giving up any negotiating leverage your airlines would have over the price of aircraft, because they have to buy from Airbus. With agriculture, there are multiple suppliers to begin with. So you can put tariffs on the U.S. And if it's tariffs on, say, pork, you can get pork from the EU, from Denmark, from Spain. You can get pork from Ukraine. You can get pork from Brazil. You can find multiple sources of global supply. And so, therefore, it tends to be an attractive way, if you're China and you feel like you want to retaliate, to put a little pressure, impose a bit of pain back on the U.S. And then there are also products, frankly, where there are luxury goods in China. And so it's pretty easy to zero them out of the market altogether. Beef, for example. I mean, China does not need to import U.S. beef. Beef is not a significant part of the consumption basket inside China. It's a luxury good, consumed at restaurants. Lobster, same sort of thing. So you can hit those kinds of sectors. And then there are, like, you know, little, small components of agricultural trade, like distillers dried grains which are sort of the residual from the production of ethanol which can be used as an animal feed. The Chinese have hit that often in the past. The Chinese is like going after chicken feet, which is going after Arkansas chicken paws. It's one of my favorites. And those tariffs are kind of fun because you can almost always see how the U.S. gets around them. You know, China puts tariffs on chicken paws and, guess what? U.S. exports of chicken paws to Hong Kong go up by almost as much as U.S. exports to China go down. So it's pretty clear that they get shipped to Hong Kong and probably taken out of one bag and put in another bag. And no one pays too much attention. But these are—it’s a classic play. And the U.S. exports 20-30 billion (dollars) a year of agricultural goods to China. Mostly soybeans. Soybeans, you can get them from Brazil. You can get them from Argentina. The last time around China zeroed out purchases of soybeans, which is a big, big component of agricultural trade, for one harvest season. And that forced U.S. beans to sell at a discount on the global market. And I think if we’re in a tariff war with China again, those kinds of retaliatory measures are 100 percent likely again. FASKIANOS: Thank you. I’m going to take a written question from Riley Anderson, who’s the deputy legislative director for New York Assemblyman Patrick Burke: Hypothetically if you were an elected official for a border district of Canada or Mexico, what would you say to your constituents about the issue? SETSER: Look, I think I would say, we benefit from a stable trading relationship with the United States. We have a challenge now because the U.S. has elected a president who doesn't always see the virtue or benefits of a stable trading relationship, even inside North America. I would say, we need to be prepared to be pragmatic. And where the U.S. has some important, realistic, legitimate concerns about the nature of trade, we should be willing and open to renegotiating parts of the U.S., Mexico, and Canada Free Trade Agreement. Call it USMCA, call it NAFTA two, it's up for renegotiation next year. We should be open to the possibility that there are beneficial to changes. In Mexico's case, Mexico is importing an awful lot of cars from China. One-third of Mexican auto demand is coming from China now, is being met by Chinese production. If the U.S. asked Mexico to raise the tariffs on imports of cars from China to match U.S. tariffs on Chinese cars, if I were Mexico, I would consider that right? The USMCA was built on the notion that it's a market where U.S. production meets Mexican demand, Mexican production meets U.S. demand, and there's an element of reciprocity. If Mexican demand is being met so heavily by China, and that's freeing up Mexican cars to be shipped north, that, to me, changes the nature of the agreement. And it's, arguably, to Mexico's interest to have more of Mexican demand to be met with cars that are made in Mexico, or cars that are made in the U.S. with Mexican parts. So be open to some changes when those changes make sense. But also be prepared, if you are—feel like the U.S. is making unreasonable demands, that you’re going to have to be prepared to take retaliatory actions and show that you can’t be bullied. And so I think there’s going to be a tough balance. And, frankly, it could be somewhat painful, for all parties, if President Trump goes forward with 25 percent tariffs with some of our closest trading partners, who have production chains that are very integrated into our own. FASKIANOS: Thank you. I’m going to go next, a raised hand from Stephanie Agee, who’s vice president and chief admin officer for international trade in Virginia. Q: Hi. Oh, excuse me. Can you hear me, OK? FASKIANOS: We can, Stephanie. Thank you. Q: Thank you. First of all, thank you all so much for hosting this. I really appreciate your time and your analysis here. Question for you. So if you were advising the president-elect, and we wanted to focus on—you rightly mentioned that there’s a number of reasons to use tariffs. If we wanted to focus on it being a source of leverage, focusing on that purpose behind them, would you advise that there are alternatives? That there are other ways to provide pressure and leverage, especially on a country like China where we’re very interested in sort of changing their trading practices and, you know, bringing them more into the way of doing things that we’re more familiar with in the U.S.? Are there—are there alternatives? Are there things that should really be much more strongly considered that are being ignored right now in favor of tariffs? SETSER: I guess a couple of thoughts and reactions. I think there probably aren't a lot of other tools of leverage vis-à-vis China. You could say, for example, that export controls are a tool of leverage. But in general, if you're doing an export control, the export control is a good that you think would—you know, where you want to keep China from having access to that good because you think if China had access to that good it would be detrimental to your national security or economic security. We don't let China buy the components to make a stealth plane. We don't let China buy the propellers for a nuclear submarine. We don't let China buy a Black Hawk helicopter. And we currently don't let China buy cutting-edge equipment to manufacture semiconductors or certain very high-performing semiconductor chips. China would love to negotiate a reduction in those export controls. So that would be one mechanism, one source of leverage that you could look to use. But, you know, in general, unless you think the export control was applied incorrectly and the good is not of national security interest, you wouldn't want to negotiate over in that field. China would like to do more investment in the U.S. Certainly they would—you know, I guess you can debate how much President Xi actually cares about it. But in principle, they would like to not be forced to divest, or their company ByteDance would like to not be forced to divest from TikTok. So you could, in some cases, negotiate over the terms of new investment or modulating requirements for divestiture. Again, you'd have to come to the conclusion that you're willing—that you don't think TikTok poses the kind of risk that has been postulated, and so therefore this is an appropriate field of negotiation. In general, I think around economic issues, the most obvious field for negotiations is, in fact, tariffs. Then you have to deal—ask, are there tariffs that you’re willing to reduce as well as tariffs that you’re willing to increase? Are there tariffs that you are willing to not increase if China makes certain policy changes? What’s the realm of negotiation? And I think there is a very, very fundamental question there. Which is, how realistic is it to get enormously significant changes in China’s way of doing business through any tool of economic leverage? China is a very big country. China managed the 15 percent increase in U.S. tariffs relatively well. China is exporting more, in aggregate—not more to the U.S., but more in aggregate—about a trillion dollars more, so a lot more in aggregate, now than it was five years ago. So there's no real evidence that, in the face of tariff threats, China is going to change the way it does business. In some sense, Xi has doubled down on China's model. And he's very committed to a model of state-led industrial and technological catch up. And so to me, it's a little hard to see where the realm of negotiation is. Xi wants to make his own semiconductors. He wants to make his own aircraft. He wants to be technologically independent. He wants Chinese electric vehicles to be the global standard. He wants Chinese electric vehicle production to meet global demand. So I'm not sure that there's—at this point, there's a realistic deal. So at least in my view, this is what I would have advised a President Harris and what I would advise a President Trump if he were to ask, is that you really need to set the tariffs on China in a way that reflects what you—what the kind of trade you want to do with China should look like. So it’s less about changing China, and more about insulating your economy from certain Chinese industrial policies that would otherwise cause you difficulties. So you want to protect electric vehicle production in the U.S. from China, because China has built up, through state support, through initially a very protected market, a big lead in electric vehicles. And you don’t want that to wipe out your own electric vehicle industry. You don’t want Tesla to meet U.S. demand just from Shanghai. So you would want to think about how you structure trade to achieve your goal, which is an electric vehicle industry in the U.S. You would want to structure trade in such a way that you don't have excessive dependence on China for certain critical materials. But you might be more open to continuing trade in toys, apparel, and bicycles. And China might remain open to trade in agriculture. So the way I would think of it is less we're going to be able to change China because I don't think you can China, and more how you want—how you want to trade with an unchanged China that is pursuing some pretty aggressive industrial policies. That's my view. I mean, it's obviously a huge source of contention and debate. FASKIANOS: I’ll take the next written question from Drew Combs, who is the executive director of the North Dakota Trade Office: If you could—I’m trying to get back to it—explain or elaborate on how the USMCA will come into play or change under President-elect Trump. SETSER: Well, that’s a very interesting question. The USMCA is already in force. It is an agreement that President Trump signed. It was negotiated by Bob Lighthizer when he was President Trump’s trade representative. And it establishes generally tariff-free trade among the countries of North America. And companies have invested and set up supply chains based on that assumption. That includes setting up auto supply chains that cross the border. Often, you know, a part will be made first stage in Mexico, second stage in the United States, third stage in Mexico, put it into an engine in the United States, and then put into a light truck in Mexico. So things cross the border lots of times. So that is, in a sense, the law of the land. If you want to change that, you either have to renegotiate USMCA—and there is a process inside the agreement that sets up a review and a renegotiation for next year. But you could pull that forward. And so in that context, you could propose changes to the USMCA agreement. One which I alluded to earlier is because it’s a free trade agreement, it’s not a customs union, the members of USMCA, Mexico, Canada, and the U.S., have different tariffs on the same good towards third parties. So Mexico has a much lower tariff on Chinese-made cars than either the U.S. or Canada. And so, hence, Mexico imports a lot more Chinese-made cars. So you might ask Mexico, in the context of a renegotiation, to adjust its tariff towards Chinese-made cars to reflect the higher tariffs now in place in the U.S. and in Canada. I’m sure Mexico would have some ask of the U.S. as well. One of the features of USMCA, unlike other free trade agreements, is that there is a—for the auto sector, there's a high wage content requirement, in addition to North American content requirement. So in order to qualify for zero tariff auto trade, as opposed to the 2 ½ percent tariff on a normal car and the 25 percent, which is much more significant, the tariff on a light truck, the car has to, or light truck, has to have a defined amount of North American content. And in addition to having a defined amount of North American content, it has to have a defined amount of content made by workers who have a wage above a certain level. I don't have it memorized. And that was more or less meant to be a—has to have a certain amount of U.S. and Canadian content, or—and this is what the Mexicans insisted on—we want to eventually have wages like the U.S. and Canada. So if wages in Mexico are high enough, we want to qualify for that high wage content component. I think one of the big issues going forward is going to be that the 25—the 2 ½ percent tariff isn't that high. And so some companies may not be interested in meeting these requirements just to get rid of that 2 ½ percent tariff. They may want to make in Mexico cars with a lot more Chinese content. And they can do so. I mean, it's a tariff on a car. If you can bring in the parts and you pay the 2 ½ percent tariff, it's fine. There's no further requirements. You're not required to meet the USMCA content requirement unless you want to get rid of that 2 ½ percent tariff. So I think there's going to be a set of issues that will be very legitimately part of the negotiation. On top of that, President Trump has made a series of threats that go outside the four corners of USMCA. There is nothing in USMCA that says that it is appropriate for the U.S. to threaten 25 percent tariffs on Mexico if Mexico doesn’t do a better job of controlling the border and helping stop immigration into the U.S., or helping stop fentanyl into the U.S. Nor actually is there any obvious component of U.S. trade law that would allow that. You would probably have to do that under the sanctions authority or IEEPA, if you can do it at all. And so that’s a threat that is outside the scope of a normal trade agreement. And that’s where I think, if President Trump goes forward with some of those kinds of threats, which are on top of and outside of USMCA, you’re effectively tearing USMCA up. And so I think that’s when it becomes a bit delicate and potentially risky. FASKIANOS: Thanks. I’m going to go next to Lanette Frazier from Arkansas. If you can state your affiliation, that’d be great. Q: Can you hear me? FASKIANOS: We can. Q: OK. Thank you so much. First of all, I want to say thank you Mr.—I’m Lanette Frazier. I’m a city councilmember here in Pine Bluff, Arkansas. And this is my first term. And so, Mr. Brad, thank you for breaking down the three ways that tariffs are used. That helped me a lot. My question might be simple to a lot, but I—since I'm on a local level. With the tariffs that President-elect Trump is suggesting or threatening he might do, how will those—how will the tariffs impact small and mid-size enterprises differently than large corporations? Because mostly here we have small or mid-size. We have few large corporations. And are there any tools or resources that are available to help businesses to navigate any changes that might come down the line? SETSER: You know, I think you should contact your local congressman or -woman for any tools or resources. That's not really my specialty. I think we can think of a lot of different ways different kinds of small businesses can be impacted. Some small businesses rely on imports for the goods that they sell, some retail businesses. And so then it really depends on are you relying on an imported good from China or not. Are there going to be tariffs on Mexico or not? Is it going to be a 10 percent across-the-board tariff—which, you know, may not be great, but you can probably afford, whereas a 60 percent tariff on a bestselling item from China may really put you at a disadvantage? So that would be the most obvious effect. Some small businesses may be exporters and may face some of the impacts of retaliation. We don't think of small farmers as small businesses, but you can think of farmers as independent businesses that produce a commodity. And that commodity, if it's hit by a tariff, they may lose some markets. The price of their goods may go down. And that can impact the local economy. And so for some places like Arkansas or Kansas, where I'm from, that effect can be significant. And then, even if you're not directly affected, if there's, say, a 10 percent tariff on everything, and the price of every imported good—so, all the stuff you buy at Walmart goes up by 10 percent, people are going to be spending more on some of those goods. You know, people are still going to buy toys, and, I don’t know, plastic hoses, because you want to spray people in the summer because that’s a nice thing to do. And therefore, you’re going to have less money in your pocket and less money to spend in small businesses that don’t actually use imports and that don’t rely on exports. I think in general, small businesses tend to be more one step removed. You know, unless you’re importing goods for sale you may not be directly affected. But there’s going to be a lot of, I would think, indirect effects. And then if a small business is a supplier to a big business, well, some will benefit, possibly, because they can take business away from an importer. But others may be hurt. If you’re supplying an exporter that’s hit by retaliation, you know you’re going to see trouble. So I think it’s hard to generalize about the impact on small business. And a lot of the impacts will be the impacts that are felt by the entire economy, not just by—directly by a small business. Q: Thanks so much. FASKIANOS: Thank you. I’m going to a written question from David Briel, who’s Pennsylvania deputy secretary of international business development: How would you advise we, from the state government, assist companies who present clear evidence of damage the specific tariff creates, and one that impedes company expansion and increased employment here in Pennsylvania to get tariff exclusions from the USTR? SETSER: Well—the first question is whether there are going to be tariff exclusions, to be honest. There may be, there may not be. Tariff exclusions are not a requirement. There have been exclusion processes in the past, but they are—there is no guarantee that there'll be a new exclusion process. And certainly, if you're going to do a 10 percent across-the-board tariff as a tool for raising revenue, you actually can't grant very many exclusions. Maybe you can do an exclusion for imports of petroleum and crude oil, but you really can't do anything else because every exclusion grows over time. You know, we don't give too many exclusions to people who pay income tax because if you give too many exclusions on people who pay income tax you won't have any income tax revenue. So if you're going to use this as a pay-for, as a source of revenue, I wouldn't expect there to be very many exclusions. You would want the people to just cough up the money because the goal is to raise revenue. If you want to get a fundamental change in the U.S. relationship with China, you might be willing to offer exclusions for a limited period of time, which is what Lighthizer did. But you would want people to have, at the end of that period of time, a plan whereby they will not be reliant on China. You want them to use this period of reprieve to adjust and find alternative suppliers. So one of the criteria in the initial round of exclusions was a plan. You needed to show that it was going to be painful in the short run to not get access to an input from China, but that you have a plan in the long run where you were going to find alternative suppliers. And Lighthizer's general view was that you know, those exclusions shouldn't be renewed. They were given to you to allow you to find—have time to find alternatives. So that'd be one approach. And, you know, your best strategy for getting to an exclusion was to show, on one level, pain and, on another level, a plan. And I think that in general is the standard advice. But the key on all this is actually whether there's an exclusion process, what are the legal criteria that are laid out for the exclusion. USTR, if they are running the exclusion, or Commerce, if it's a Commerce authority, have to be sensitive to charges of favoritism. And so there has to be some kind of criteria and process for evaluating which exclusions are granted and which ones are denied. So looking at those criteria, and then to the extent the criteria are established, fitting the—you know, the basics, fitting the argument to the criteria that have been set out in the most compelling way, is how you get an exclusion. But I am not at all convinced there's going to be that many exclusions from some of these tariffs. FASKIANOS: Thank you. I’m going to go next to Chris Himes, who has his hand up, from the township manager of New Garden Township in Pennsylvania. Q: Representing a flood of Pennsylvanian-type questions here. But I represent a township. It serves as one of the largest epicenters of mushroom production in the United States coming from Pennsylvania. So with that, obviously, a tariff type policy where it’s—no doubt, it’s inordinately skewed to coming from China. It’s, like, over 90 percent. So with that, it would be very interesting when there’s such, like, a strong production coming from one entity to the other how tariffs would influence that. It’s funny too, because Canada is actually up in the top five as well, which doesn’t really help out. But then if you take that decision from a policy, and you were to combine that with a mass deportation type of policy, which would impact a lot of the mushroom production capabilities, I would just be very curious about how they would exist in concert with each other. SETSER: I guess all I’ll say is that I’m very curious as well. I mean, you have offsetting shocks. So the protection, the higher tariffs on Chinese mushrooms, should be an incentive for more domestic production of mushrooms. But I guess mushrooms are pretty labor intensive, and so therefore a reduction in the supply of low-wage labor in the U.S. would work against you. It’s an empirical question, as far as I’m concerned, and I don’t know the answer. FASKIANOS: I’m going to try to do a roundup of three questions that are focused on the impact of President Trump-elect’s plan on specific industries: Steven Foutes from Missouri about the impact on travel, tourism; Mayor Maldonado from Nogales, Arizona about why we would—there would be tariffs on Mexico on fresh produce, fruits and vegetables; and John Boyd about the ban on crude oil from Russia. And I think he’s coming in from Washington city—Kent, Washington city. So, can you just talk about those specific industries? SETSER: Well, crude from Russia is sort of a separate case because that is less of a trade policy and more of a sanction or a punitive policy. We didn't—you know, there's not enormous amounts of crude that never came from Russia. I think we got some fuel oil for a while, but crude is a relatively fungible commodity. You know, yes, there are refiners that are optimized around certain grades, and it can be complicated and difficult to make adjustments, but at the end of the day oil is oil, and you can generally find alternative sources of supply. So I think my sense is that we've adapted relatively well to the tariffs. And I think there may be a blocking sanction as well, a block, on payments for Russian crude. And that, to me, is just—you know, it's a byproduct of a decision that we wanted to put pressure on Russia. And it's a relatively low-cost way for the U.S. to put a bit of pressure on Russia because there are alternative sources of supply for crude. The big issue around Russia, of course, is that while we have limited our imports of Russian crude, and we've tried to make it hard for tankers to ship Russian crude unless Russian crude is sold at a discount, most Russian crude goes to China and to India, and they have a different view. So the issue around Russia is really how to—or, whether to, and then how, to further reduce Russia's overall oil revenues as a source of pressure to get them into a settlement. And then, I guess, if you ask if there's a settlement would that change? I think with President Trump one never knows. But personally, I think it's pretty unlikely, just because I don't think Russia thinks of the U.S. as a critical long-run market for its crude, given our own strong domestic oil industry. So, travel is probably not going to be directly affected. Travel will probably be indirectly affected, because tariffs tend to lead to changes in exchange rates. So, when you put a tariff on, say, China, China tends to let its currency depreciate. If you put a tariff on Europe, it hurts Europe's economy. The European Central Bank would likely lower interest rates and the euro would go down. And so, when the euro goes down more Americans go to Europe for vacation and fewer Europeans come to the U.S. for a vacation. So, travel may not be directly impacted by any of these tariff threats. Again, if you do stuff that is more around the nature of tightening the border, making the border tougher, making it harder to get into the U.S., that does have an impact. I don't think of that as trade policy. I think of that as a border enforcement policy. That certainly has an impact. I mean, I don't know. I've been traveling back and forth a little with Europe and, like, the European passport control, where you just show up and they take your photo automatically, and you get in and out in five minutes, it's a noticeable difference between getting into the U.S. when you have to go through the Newark or Dulles Airport lines, which can take you an hour. I mean, it is an impediment to coming to the U.S., I think. But the biggest effect, classic effect, would be through the exchange rate and how the exchange rate changes incentives for tourism. Food, produce, fruit, you know, the avocado question. Do we really want to pay more for avocados from Mexico? Personally, I don’t. So I’d be very happy if there were an exclusion for avocados and other fresh produce from Mexico. There are some categories of fresh produce from Mexico which competes with California and Florida production. So then it becomes a choice, a very direct choice, between consumers who benefit from more choice and lower price from having access to Mexican produce and domestic producers who tend to be a little higher cost who run the risk of losing out if there aren’t some frictions, tariffs, limits on Mexican exports to the U.S. I think it is a—becomes an interesting question if we’re doing something that’s fairly across the board. Do you have exclusions for—I don’t think you can have many—in an across-the-board, 10 percent tariff, I don’t think you can have many exclusions for a country, because if you do an exclusion for autos from Mexico, everyone will want to make their autos for the U.S. in Mexico. It becomes an ever-growing workaround for the tariffs. But I do think you can grant exclusions for well-defined products. So crude oil for Canada and for Mexico, since we can bring it in and refine it. Conceivably, some specialized, you know, avocados or something else, where—coffee, you could imagine that being subject to an exclusion. But these are choices that become important when you’re doing something that is an across-the-board tariff. Remember, if the across-the-board tariff’s goal is to raise revenue, you want to have the biggest possible base of revenue. And that means raising the price of things we import, even if there aren’t alternative sources. It’s just a way of—you know, it’s like a sales tax. And, you know, on a sales tax, you generally—you want to apply it pretty broadly. FASKIANOS: All right. I’m going to defy Council rules and go over just with this final question, which I think is the perfect one to end on, from Joan Lee, from the Louisiana mayor’s office. I think I got that right: How important do you think will subnational diplomacy be? Or will it play any role in leveraging against the effects of tariffs or some of the consequential economic actions by this incoming administration? And my apologies, it’s the office of the Los Angeles Mayor. So my apologies on that. So this is the final question, Brad. A big one. SETSER: Yeah. Look, I don't know. Why don't I know? President-elect Trump won a mandate. He won a mandate. He campaigned very clearly on tariffs. No one can say that they will be surprised by Trump's tariffs. We saw tariffs under his first administration. He says, I think tariffs are the most beautiful word in the English language, that they need a public relations agency. And he tends to suggest tariffs in contexts where no one had thought of using tariffs before, the whole 51st state with Canada thing and Canadian immigration, or tariffs on Brazil because Brazil hasn’t shot down these ideas for a BRICS currency, which are going nowhere. But that was sort of—that’s not a normal use of tariffs. He really does seem personally to believe in tariffs. And since the president has been delegated a certain amount of authority by Congress, that authority—you know, whether it’s the 232 authority to impose tariffs if that product is a national security threat, the Section 301 authority to impose tariffs after an investigation if a country is imposing—has unfair policies towards the U.S., unfair, burdensome policies towards U.S. commerce. So it’s an economic authority. Potentially the authority under the International Emergency Economic Powers Act, which is the sanctions authority, if there’s a national security threat. Defined a little differently than the Section 232 national security authority, to put on sanctions. And those sanctions could potentially be structured as tariffs. There’s authority in the event of a balance of payments emergency to put it on, for 150 days, an across-the-board, 15 percent tariff. These are authorities that are vested in the president. They've already—authority that's already been granted by Congress to the presidency. So in the first instance, neither Congress nor subnational governments have any control, other than lobbying, and pressuring public. It is the authority the president has. And it's up to the president to decide how to use it. Over time, if a president overuses this delegated authority, Congress—not necessarily subnational governments—can pull that back. And so I think a lot of the impact that subnational governments will have will come if there is some kind of consensus that President Trump has overused the delegation of authority, the tariffing authority, that rests with the president. And then I think sub-nationals, through representatives, senators, so forth and so on—because the legal authority to impose tariffs resides not at the state level. It resides at the federal level. And it is an authority of the Congress. And so the president only has this authority because Congress has, under existing law, delegated some of its intrinsic power to the presidency. So I don't know that there's a direct role for subnational governments. I think there's a big indirect role because I think elected representatives like talking to other elected representatives. And those who represent California, Louisiana, or Pennsylvania in Congress will take cues from what they hear from their constituents. But right now, for the first year, at least my judgment is, it’s going to be very much a game driven by how far President Trump wants to take and use the various authorities that have, over time, already been granted to the president. And then I think the second act will be if he overdoes that, how much Congress and the public want to pull back some of that authority. That's my guess. FASKIANOS: Brad Setser, thank you very much for your analysis today. We really appreciate it. And to all of you for your questions and comments. I’m sorry we could not get to them, but we will obviously be following this closely. I think this is at the top of the agenda. You can sign up for Brad’s blog, Follow the Money. And I also encourage you to sign up for our RealEcon newsletter. This is the CFR initiative reimagining American economic leadership that’s headed up by Matt Goodman. So, we are—we are doing a lot of work in this area, and would love to have your input. As always, we invite you to visit CFR.org, ForeignAffairs.com, and ThinkGlobalHealth.org for the latest developments and analysis on international trends and how they’re affecting the U.S. You can email us suggestions for future webinars. You can email us at [email protected]. We look forward to your feedback and to your continued participation. Thank you for all you’re doing in your communities. And we wish you a happy holiday. And we will reconvene in 2025. So, thank you all. Thanks, Brad. SETSER: Sure. END
  • China
    China’s Stunning 2024 Export Growth
    Chinese exports are growing much faster in volume than in dollar terms. Europe is losing out.
  • China
    Why Did China’s Current Account Surplus Surge in the Third Quarter?
    An old school, “make blogging great again” style post. The rise in the current account surplus might be linked to the “carry” unwind in the third quarter.

Experts in this Keyword

Heidi Crebo-Rediker
Heidi Crebo-Rediker

Senior Fellow

Matthijs Headshot
Matthias Matthijs

Senior Fellow for Europe

Brad Setser
Brad W. Setser

Whitney Shepardson Senior Fellow

Benn Steil
Benn Steil

Senior Fellow and Director of International Economics

  • RealEcon
    The Surprising Resilience of Globalization: An Examination of Claims of Economic Fragmentation
    In my new paper published by the Aspen Economic Strategy Group, I highlight the persistence of unhealthy globalization and lay out some proposals for a more sustainable regime. 
  • United States
    The Millennium Challenge Corporation at 20: Progress and Prospects
    Play
    Panelists reflect on the past, present, and future of the Millennium Challenge Corporation (MCC) having reached its twentieth anniversary of operation, as well as the future of economic diplomacy and the challenging landscape of global poverty. This meeting series is presented by RealEcon: Reimagining American Economic Leadership, a CFR initiative of the Maurice R. Greenberg Center for Geoeconomic Studies. 
  • China
    Tracking China’s Control of Overseas Ports
    This interactive map tracks China’s growing maritime influence through investments in strategic overseas ports. Users can plot the location of each port and view satellite images alongside detailed information on the share of Chinese ownership, the total amount of Chinese investment, and the port’s suitability for use by the Chinese military.
  • Economics
    Global Trade Tracker
    The CFR Global Trade Tracker allows you to gauge trends in international trade through time. The map below compiles trade data from 178 countries as reported to the International Monetary Fund (IMF). It displays values for each country’s trade in tangible goods and, for countries reporting the necessary data to the IMF, it also shows the value on their current accounts (that is, adding in services trade, payments to investors abroad, and other foreign funds transfers). For both current-account and goods-trade data, you can choose to view countries’ exports, imports, total trade volume, or balance of trade. You can also choose to see the data in U.S. dollars or as a share of countries’ gross domestic product (GDP). Use the drop-down menu above the map to select which figures to display. Hover over a particular country to see its latest data and, to view changes over time, adjust the date using the slider above the map. Dollar-denominated data appears on the map as circles, and each circle’s area scales with the size of that country’s trade. Countries are shaded according to their share of GDP, with darker shading signaling more trade. Countries with a positive trade balance are colored in green, while those with a negative balance are colored in orange. The data highlights significant trends in global trade. It shows, among other things, how trade plunges during recessions and climbs during recovery. In the third quarter of 2009, for example, one year after the onset of the Great Recession, global goods trade plunged by 25 percent from the year prior (by 10 percent of each country’s GDP, on average). Trade then climbed higher over the subsequent decade but fell sharply again during the COVID-19 pandemic. By the second quarter of 2022, goods trade had risen back to pre-pandemic levels. After moderating over the course of 2022, it fell mildly in 2023. Factors weighing on trade include depressed demand owing to high borrowing costs, falling commodity prices, and growing tensions between China and the West.    You can also view historical trade data for each country on the chart below. Select a country with the left drop-down menu and which category to display with the right one. To the left of the chart, you can see the selected country’s most recent trade figures and average tariff rates. For sixty large national economies, the chart also displays data on each country's bilateral trade relationships with its largest trading partners.   As both the map and the chart show, the dollar value of global trade has grown markedly over the past three decades. Some of this rise owes to increased globalization, but price inflation has also played a role in the dollar data. Countries’ share-of-GDP numbers, which strip out most of the inflation effects, have naturally risen more slowly. Please also visit our Global Monetary Policy Tracker, Global Imbalances Tracker, Global Growth Tracker, Global Energy Tracker, Sovereign Risk Tracker, and Central Bank Currency Swaps Tracker. Data Notes The map above shows goods-trade and current-account figures for countries that report them to the IMF’s Balance of Payments dataset. All trade data is shown as four-quarter rolling sums, as is current-account data for countries that report quarterly. Otherwise, data is annual. GDP figures come from the IMF’s International Financial Statistics (IFS) dataset, except for Venezuela after 2012, for Myanmar prior to 2013, and for cases in which the IFS has not yet published a country’s figures. In those cases, GDP numbers come from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook. For each country, its top three trading partners are defined as those countries with which it has the greatest goods-trade volume over the most recent eight quarters of data.
  • World Order
    Council of Councils Thirteenth Annual Conference
    Coordination is needed on growing transnational challenges, but domestic political priorities could hinder reaching consensus on managing global challenges.
  • Economics
    Global Growth Tracker: World Economies by GDP
    This tracker charts the economic growth performance through time of ninety-one countries around the globe.
  • China
    Power and Financial Interdependence
    My new paper for the Geoeconomics and Geofinance Initiative of the Institute Français des Relations Internationals’ (IFRI) explores the history of the Sino-American financial relationship.
  • Economics
    State and Local Officials Webinar on RealEcon: Reimagining American Economic Leadership
    Play
    Matthew Goodman, distinguished fellow and director of the Greenberg Center for Geoeconomic Studies at CFR, discusses CFR’s new RealEcon initiative and the role of state and local officials in contributing to a consensus on U.S. leadership in the international economy. A listening session follows his opening remarks, during which Matt poses a series of questions on American economic leadership and solicit feedback from participants. TRANSCRIPT FASKIANOS: I’m Irina Faskianos, vice president for the National Program and Outreach here at CFR.  CFR is an independent and nonpartisan membership organization, think tank, and publisher focused on U.S. foreign policy. CFR is also the publisher of Foreign Affairs magazine. And, as always, CFR takes no institutional position on matters of policy. Through our State and Local Officials Initiative, CFR serves as a resource on international issues affecting the priorities and agendas of state and local governments by providing analysis on a wide range of policy topics. We appreciate you all taking the time to be with us for this very special session of this webinar series. We’re delighted to have over 200 participants confirmed from forty-seven U.S. states and territories. As a reminder, the webinar is on the record. The video and transcript will be posted on our website after the fact at CFR.org.  So we’re pleased to have Matthew Goodman with us today to lead this discussion. Matthew Goodman is a distinguished fellow and the director of the Greenberg Center for Geoeconomic Studies at CFR, where he recently launched CFR’s newest initiative, RealEcon, Reimagining American Economic Leadership. And the purpose of this initiative—I’ll leave it to him to tell you the reason why the Council has mounted this initiative. Prior to joining CFR, he served as senior vice president for economics and the Simon chair in political economy at the Center for Strategic and International Studies. He’s served as director for international economics on the National Security Council staff, undersecretary for economic affairs at the State Department, and as an international economist at the U.S. Treasury Department. So, Matt, thank you very much for being with us.  Just to set the table, the format for today’s webinar is as follows: Matt will introduce the goals of RealEcon, and how officials at the state and local level can contribute to the dialogue on American economic leadership. We’ll run a short poll after his remarks and have a guided discussion on the U.S. and the international economy. So we’re very much looking forward to hearing your views and getting your insights in this conversation. And I’m going to now turn it over to Matt to take it away from here. GOODMAN: Great. Well, thanks, Irina. It’s a pleasure to be here. And welcome, everyone, to the Council on Foreign Relations. I’m in Washington here where we have our satellite—more than a satellite office, I guess, our co-headquarters down here, as well as New York. But delighted to be with you here for this great opportunity for me. I hope you’ll get something out of it too, but it’s really—it’s really important to my work. So, as Irina said, I’ve been here about six, seven months. And I’ve been building this new project, new initiative called RealEcon, which is short for Reimagining American Economic Leadership. And what we’re trying to do is to have a conversation about America’s role in the international economy, why and whether that matters to U.S. interests, and to Americans. And to try to work towards something more like a durable consensus for a kind of American engagement that benefits us and the rest of the world in the best possible way. As you know, just a tiny bit of background, you know, the U.S. really created the international economic system that emerged after World War II, when we were the biggest kid on the block, and we created all these institutions like the World Bank and the IMF. We created kind of the rules of the road. And that was good for everybody. It was good for us—or, most people. Good for us, good for people around the world. But something started to change, you know, as early as the 1970s but certainly in more recent times, that has eroded the support for that American role as a kind of leader and champion of this international economic order. And so we want to understand why that has eroded and what to do about it, and whether, you know, this is something to be spending a lot of policy time here in Washington trying to fix. Which, you know, I’ll be honest, we think it is worth it. But we want to hear from people.  So the first thing we’re doing—and we’re going to dig into different issues of trade and investment. We’re going to get into foreign assistance, which has been a main tool of U.S. policy, foreign aid. We’re going to talk about the new topic of economic security, which is really about how we manage risks—like the rise of China, like climate change, and supply chain disruptions, other risks that have emerged in the international economy that need kind of new policy solutions. We’re going to, in our project, dig into all of those things. And we’ll give you a little pop quiz about some of that stuff later so we can get a sense of what you think.  But the first thing we’re doing in this project really is a listening tour. And we’ve been around now to a couple of states. We were in Florida last month. We were in Wisconsin last week meeting with local officials, businesspeople, students, journalists, dairy farmers, and ginseng farmers in northern Wisconsin—which was fantastic. And we’re asking them about the issues that we’re going to discuss here today, and that are included in this pop quiz. Don’t worry, there’s no—it’s all pass/fail, and you’ll pass. But we are—think this is really important. And this opportunity and meeting with all of you in this format—I hope we can all meet in person too—but this is a convenient way for us to tap into your knowledge, expertise views. And, you know, views not only as officials, but as kind of citizens of the United States. What do you think about things like trade, and so forth?  So with that background, I’m willing—you know, along the way here I think I can see when you raise your hand. If I can’t, I’ll put up a—send up a flare. But, you know, if there are any sort of fundamental questions about the project, I would welcome those. But what we could do here, I think, is jump straight into the—into this quiz. And then we’ll go through some of the answers. So if, Emily, you’re controlling the quiz, maybe you could put that up here. And it’s just five questions. And I’ll give you all kind of a minute or two to go through and answer. It’s multiple-choice. It’s not challenging. And you can just—your answers won’t be personalized. I mean, we won’t know who answered what. But we’ll get some kind of sense of the room from these results.  I am not seeing the poll. I don’t know whether I’m supposed to be or I’m in the wrong place. But, Emily, or—oh, there it is. OK. So I think you can control the scrolling up and down on your screen. That is, you know, the audience in the webinar. So please just—I’ll stop talking and just take a minute to go through and answer these five questions. And then we’ll talk about them. I’m still here, in case anyone’s worried that they’ve lost the connection. I’m going to give you another thirty seconds. Not sure if I’m allowed to answer, it just occurred to me. OK. Folks think they’ve had enough time, I hope? OK. I hope everybody was able to see those and able to answer them. Again, fairly straightforward questions and don’t require a huge amount of thought, I hope. OK. With that, maybe, Emily, if you could share the results. We have this amazing technology to be able to show you—and if you—if everyone watching could just not scroll down and just focus one question at a time, because I really would like to try to get—try to get some feedback on each of these questions.  So what I will first do is this first question: Which of the following captures best what most people in your state think about international trade? And it seems as though we have a close tie between very good thing and somewhat good thing. But most importantly is that a total of 88 percent of you who at least think it’s somewhat of a good thing. And that’s interesting and not totally inconsistent with the polling done by a Pew Research, or by the Chicago Council, and other polling outfits, that show, you know, something between two-thirds and three-quarters of the American people in answer to this kind of question-answer affirmatively that it is least somewhat good.  But I’d like to challenge people, if we can do this in a sort of timely way, if anybody is brave enough to raise their hand who voted for the somewhat bad thing option—if someone’s willing to raise their hand and explain to us all why they voted that way, and why they think, you know, that their state is not so positive. Is anybody brave enough? And I just want to make sure that we’re going to be able to capture this person. I don’t so far see any hands. Could some brave person just put up their hand using the raise-hand button at the bottom and just even—actually, if you could just even—somebody who’s brave, just put that up and say hello, so I can make sure that I can actually see the raise-hand function, which I am still not seeing.  And I just want to give another thirty seconds to make sure it’s not just that you’re—it’s not just a technical problem here that I’m not seeing it, as opposed to people just being shy. Can somebody—there we go. There are raised hands. OK, I can’t—oh, there they are. OK, well, I see the—I see chat. I don’t see the raised-hand function anywhere. So could somebody from our team, Emily or Andrew or somebody, just call on someone and recognize them, and then have them identify themselves, and then go ahead and try to answer my question?  OPERATOR: Sure. We have Sean Smith.  GOODMAN: OK, Sean. Go ahead and identify yourself, if you would, where you are and what you do. Yeah, go ahead. Q: So I was trying to help you overcome your technical challenges. I was more in the somewhat positive realm, although I think it depends on which of my constituents you’re talking about. So I’m— GOODMAN: Where are you? Where are you? Q: Yeah, Jackson County, Missouri, which is Kansas City, and the suburbs of that. And I will say that the biggest thing that seems to be pointing people toward it being less positive recently is when we seen some of the issues with respect to our supply chain—whether that was in pharmaceuticals or semiconductors. We see that this overreliance on foreign trade results in us not being totally able to take care of ourselves, puts us at risk for economic and security disruptions. And I think that’s pointing people towards the less positive feelings on foreign trade. GOODMAN: I see. OK. And, I mean, can you give an example of a business or sort of type of activity that people are— Q: Yeah. So medication, right? Certain medications that help people that have ADD right now are in limited supply. And there’s just this very basic understanding that that comes from challenges that are outside of the United States, getting these ingredients. And the idea that we just outsource so many things that, you know, we can’t necessarily take care of ourselves the way we used to. People don’t like that. GOODMAN: Got it. That’s really interesting and helpful. And I have now discovered in my great technological capability where—I’ve just discovered where the hands are. So now I—now I do see the hands. And I see that Lystra McCoy has raised her hand. Lystra, go ahead. Q: Yes. Hi. This is Lystra McCoy. GOODMAN: Lystra, sorry. Q: And I am a Monroe County legislator in Rochester, New York, Monroe County area.  So I did put somewhat a bad thing. I’m looking at recently, the Biden and Harris administration designated our area as a tech hub for semiconductor and manufacturing supply chain stability. So we’re—in the area, we look at it as, you know, we’re keeping jobs in home, high labor in the area. So we’re keeping jobs in home, or in the country, and not shipping them out. We’re also keeping money within the country by building locally and building within the country. GOODMAN: That’s, you think, a sort of widely held view, or there are a lot of people, or at least some significant portion of your— Q: There’s a significant portion. GOODMAN: Is that based on kind of current reality or sort of historical experience with—you know, I know I happen to have a favorite aunt who lives in Rochester, and I know the city has been through some hard times historically. But is that what kind of some of this is based on? Q: Yes, absolutely. I would say that it’s based on history. And then right now, I think the labor movement is really big here, big on American jobs, big on American manufacturing, and keeping things—especially, you know, we’re old rust belt in this area, looking to revive the area and bring that technology, bring that economy back. You know, Rochester, known for Xerox, Bausch + Lomb, and Kodak. So kind of to bring that essence back to the area.  GOODMAN: Interesting. Yeah. A good point. That’s really interesting. Thank you, Lystra, for that. And I’ll take Eric January. If you’re—go ahead and unmute and go ahead and make your point, if you would. Go ahead, Eric. You have to unmute, I think. Your hand’s down, but you’re still muted. I don’t know whether the— Q: Can you hear me now? GOODMAN: There we go. Go ahead. Q: OK, great. All right. Yeah. Excuse me, one second. All right. Yeah. So my name is Eric January. I’m CPA and also the clerk treasurer for the town of Merrillville, recently elected.  GOODMAN: Town of? Q: Merrillville, Indiana, the largest town— GOODMAN: Oh, Merrillville, Indiana. Got it. Great. Q: Yes. Right. So I’ve been opposed to the type of trade—and, first of all, when I mentioned, I’m in steel capital, the steel capital of the world where people benefited from the Trump tariffs on Chinese steel. But prior to that, I’m from the Chicagoland area, for the most part. I wrote a book way back in 2005 basically explaining what the first gentleman articulated, is that when we are outsourcing the majority of our goods because of, quote/unquote, “cheaper labor,” what it ultimately ended up doing is creating a level of dependency where we lose—we lose not only the jobs that were associated with it, but we ultimately end up losing the skills, and we become dependent on other people to produce things that we’re more than capable of doing. For no other reason, because it’s cheaper.  And I just think that it creates a lot of economic problems down the road, which manifested during the pandemic when we couldn’t even get our—(inaudible, technical difficulties)—because the Chinese were deciding to keep the stuff for themselves and we had to outsource all of the manufacturing. The same thing with Taiwan Semiconductor. We’re at the—at risk of going to war over producing—China invading Taiwan, because we really don’t want to lose Taiwan Semiconductor. But we started the chip industry, and we decided to outsource it to somebody else, and we created a dependency that’s completely unnatural. So there are a number of reasons, but just to be dependent on anybody as an adult is completely unnatural. It is not about the money. That is completely unnatural. And I think that it’s a setup for failure in the American economy.  GOODMAN: OK. That’s a—that’s a really clear and convincing perspective. And I want to take just one more, which I assume is going to be also somebody who voted in that category, Booter. And then I want to maybe invite—while I’m waiting for Booter to unmute and make a comment, just to say to other people who have heard those comments who voted in the more positive category, either very good thing or somewhat good thing, if there’s anything you want to say in response to any of that, feel free to jump in. Although we’ll have other chances as we go through the other questions. Booter, do you want to go ahead?  Q: Well, actually I was just raising my hand for your technical stuff. But I do have a point from—that I agree with, that the gentleman that just spoke about the outsourcing stuff. But also, I’m in Tallahassee, Florida. But I think down here, especially in the agricultural business with a lot of international trade and exports to other countries, it has been a benefit to Florida. So it’s kind of a mixed bag, I think, from our point of view. GOODMAN: Really good point. And, Booter, we were in Tallahassee—I’d mentioned we were in Florida last month. We were in Tallahassee. I’m sorry we didn’t meet. But, yeah, we heard—we heard some of that. Although, we also heard, you know, tomato growers down there who felt a little threatened by the Mexican competition when the NAFTA agreement was renegotiated, and sort of were concerned about that. So you hear—you hear that as well. But you’re making a very good point. Q: It’s really a mixed bag, I think.  GOODMAN: Yeah. But you’re definitely—you hear a lot from the agriculture sector that are looking for—you know, for foreign markets. The trade is important.  Anybody else want to jump in on this question? Otherwise, we can go down. And we’re not going to leave the topic of trade, so you’ll have other chances to jump in. But I just wanted—if anybody wanted to respond to any of the points that were made there.  Oh, Eric, did you have something else to say, or are you still— Q: Oh, I guess I didn’t lower my hand.  GOODMAN: Oh, no problem. No worries. OK. Well, why don’t we—well, let me just say one thing. Those are all really good points. And I think—I guess—actually, maybe I have a question for you, Eric, because you mentioned the point about the steel industry valuing the Trump tariffs. Actually, you know what? Let me—let me make this point when we get to the second question, because it gets right to this question. So why don’t we look at the—scroll down, everybody, to question number two, or answer number two. And the question was about, you know, how people in your state feel about tariffs imposed by the U.S. government on imported goods. And it looks like a pretty strong majority here feel that targeted tariffs are justified to protect some American firms. And it sounds like, Eric, you’re in that category. At least that category, if not the broad¬-based tariffs. Are others who voted that way—oh, go ahead, Eric. Do you want to say something? Q: No, I’m undoubtedly in that category of targeted tariffs, and maybe tariffs just in general, because at the end of the day governments have to result in tariffs because people are going for the lowest priced goods because they’re out to make some money. But that can be short sighted, in a sense, because they understand that people need jobs, but they’re trying to protect their interests and thinking in the short term. In the long term, it ends up costing the economy. And the only solution to that, in many cases, is to implement a tariff, so the price equals one another. And people are just making decision about who they want to employ, an American or a Chinese? GOODMAN: Right. That makes a lot of sense. But let me just give you another story from our road trip. We were in Wisconsin last week. And we went to a canning factory for canned green beans and other vegetables. That is—I guess it’s OK to say—it was Del Monte, was the brand. And they pick the beans locally and Americans are picking them and then putting them into the cans. But the cans are procured—there’s a factory next door that makes the cans using steel that is both imported and domestically sourced from U.S. Steel and other great steel companies.  And they said that when the tariffs—at this factory, they said when the tariffs were imposed on imported steel—not just from China, but remember it was also Korea, and Japanese, European steel that was also hit—that caused a rise in the price of the steel used in those cans, and made those cans of beans that Del Monte produces less competitive than cans of beans coming from China with, you know, China’s steel over there, with beans over there, than coming over here tariff-free and competing with the—with the Chinese—with the Del Monte beans.  And so the people in the Del Monte company were concerned about whether they were going to be able to support their position and job. So, you know, there are these sort of downstream effects are caused if you—if you put tariffs on, you know, inputs like steel, and, you know, I’d welcome response to you—from you, Eric, or others who voted that, you know, tariffs are either not a good thing or are only justified in some cases. Is there anybody who wants to—Tom Smith, you want to say something about that? Please identify yourself first, if you would. And you have to unmute here. Still not—there we go. Q: Can you hear me now?  GOODMAN: Yeah. Q: OK. Tom Smith, mayor pro tem, Weddington, North Carolina, which is a—basically, a suburb of Charlotte, North Carolina.  So we were in the area that was the textile hub of the U.S., which was decimated. And things have transitioned. But I look at—and I’ll say this, I’m a retired banker. And I’ve financed a lot of companies domestically and internationally. And when we first started the international part, I thought this was pretty good. We’d get cheap things for the consumers. And unfortunately, you know, the business gravitated heavily to China. And once we let them in the WTO, everything that—I think the wheels just came off of the fairness factor of competition. It is so difficult to compete with people who do not have the same values.  And back in the textile industry, there was a time they were importing finished apparel into our country lower than the world market price for the cotton. So how can anybody compete against trade tactics like that? So—and that goes on with the steel industry. They’re heavily subsidized. You know, Nucor Steel is headquartered in Charlotte. And I know the CFO real well. And they’re—and they’re the lowest-cost producer in the world, if you take away tariffs—not tariffs, but subsidies. And subsidies are the issues they have to compete against. Not production. The cost of a facility, the machinery and equipment, is a huge part of it. The cost of capital is the same around the world. Labor is an insignificant part of the whole component of making the steel.  It is regulations and subsidies that are the main factors against them. And I’ll just say this, the U.S. did a great job of exporting what were deemed to be polluting companies to Asia. That’s what we effectively did, because they didn’t have the same environmental rules as we do. We cleaned up our water and air to a huge degree at the expense of them. And that’s where we are. But the price was hollowing out our manufacturing base. So I think it is just terribly difficult to work with a country like China, where their idea of the rules and the rest of the world’s is something else. Europe is going through that heavily right now with China. We have a lot of German businesses in our town—not—in our area. And, you know, what goes on with China affects them. And they’re having tremendous issues with competition and— GOODMAN: Especially now, from electric vehicles and— Q: Oh, everything. Everything. And— GOODMAN: No, that’s a really good—sorry. Go ahead. Q: Yeah. But, I mean, I look at the point that they do not play—I mean, the worst thing, in my mind, the Western world ever did was allow China in the WTO. This decimated manufacturing jobs in the U.S. and Europe, and took—and took away the ability to work with the Caribbean and Central American countries for labor, to employ them by doing, you know, the labor-intensive work of, let’s say, a textile industry or your car. It just took it away. You know, everything—you know, it was all taken away and gravitated to one place. So I financed a lot of Chinese businesses over the years as they imported in here, their import operations. And basically regret every minute of it now. But they’re very good—very good businessmen. But when it comes to equity and fairness in trade, that’s not in their vocabulary. GOODMAN: Right. So I really appreciate those comments, Tom. And I—when I—as I—as I—let me say a couple things in response to that. But let me—let me invite others who want to jump in on this question about tariffs if they want to raise their hand and contribute, you’re very welcome.  All good points. And, you know, in theory, the WTO system that we created had rules about things like subsidies, right? And that you can’t subsidize, you know, to create these unfair advantages. And if you do, you can be subject to penalties, you know, the other country can retaliate, and so forth. That was, I think, constructed at a time before China was really such a big part of the WTO. It wasn’t even in the WTO when those rules were created. And I think it envisaged a different kind of scale of subsidization. You know, it was more targeted, specific subsidies. And China, you know, was over time seen to be massively subsidizing a lot of their production. And that—the WTO, at least a lot of people would argue, is not fit for purpose to try to constrain those subsidies. They’re just too massive and too widespread. So that is a big part of the debate now about trade policy.  On the other hand, it raises the point that the purpose, at least in theory, of trade policy is to try to not just open markets in both directions, but also to try to establish those kinds of rules, that then subject countries to, you know, penalties if they don’t, including your environmental point. You know, raising standards there and having penalties of countries don’t live up to those. That’s the theory. Whether it’s actually been done or implementable is another question. But that’s—but if we—if we don’t try to do trade policy rules, then, you know, you could argue that that’s going to create even more of these problems. I think that’s that would be the argument on that. But your points are very well taken, and very well-articulated. Thank you, Tom.  Did Gail want to jump in here? Go ahead, Gail. You need to unmute there. Q: All right. Can you hear me now?  GOODMAN: Yeah.  Q: Yes. Thank you. My name is Gail Patterson-Gladney, I’m a Van Buren County commissioner in Michigan.  And I represent a lot of farmers, blueberry farmers. And I don’t know if that will be classified under what you’re discussing now, but because lot of the farmers are undercut in their prices by Canada and Mexico, they are struggling. And I don’t know if it’s because they don’t have enough tariffs on those crops coming into the country, but I didn’t know if you could clarify that.  GOODMAN: That’s really interesting. And I don’t know the blueberry business. But I—but I understand from, you know, again, having just been in Wisconsin, where there’s a lot of dairy and other—actually ginseng too—where there’s competition with Canada, in particular, that you hear things like what you just said about blueberries. And that is, you know, a part of the story here, that there’s competition from especially these neighboring countries, but also, you know, China and other places, that can make it harder for, you know, American producers to compete.  And, you know, I—again, I don’t know about the blueberry case, and what kinds of tariffs we might impose, or do impose, or might impose on those, and how they’re treated under the U.S.-Canada-Mexico Free Trade Agreement. But the—you know, the—you know, it’s very—just like any other product that we put tariffs on, that can help provide some protection to or level that sort of competitive playing field. On the other hand, you know, as I was mentioning, in the steel can case with Del Monte, you know, it probably ends up raising prices for consumers and for folks, as it were, downstream of that—of that production. So that’s the—that’s the sort of trade-off here, if we were to use tariffs, you know, on a product like blueberries. But interesting point. Thank you. I didn’t—maybe need to get up to Michigan and see the blueberry business up there at some point. Q: Yes. OK. Thank you. GOODMAN: That’s very helpful. Thank you, Gail. Q: You’re welcome. GOODMAN: I mean, unless there are other points on that, and I’d welcome other points on trade, we’ll probably have a chance to circle back on that. But I do want to get through the other questions, and then we can have a period at the end there, of just sort of open comments that anybody wants to make. But, so number three, if we could scroll down to that. We asked you about foreign aid. And the question is, does—you know, do folks in your state think that foreign aid is mostly good for the U.S. or mostly harms the U.S.? And it seems like—unless there were just two people who answered and it was a tie—there seem to be sort of split views here. And I wondered if anybody wanted to take that on. I see Lynette has got her hand up. I don’t know whether it’s this question or the previous one. Either one is fine. Go ahead. Lanette. Q: It’s this one, Can you hear me?  GOODMAN: OK. Yes, ma’am. Go ahead. Q: It’s this one. And let me preface it by saying that my citizens here—I’m from Pine Bluff, Arkansas. I’m a city council member here. And I do know that—let me preface it by saying that there are a lot of— GOODMAN: Oops, we lost you there. At least I can’t hear Lanette anymore. FASKIANOS: I think Lanette, you muted herself. There you go. GOODMAN: There you go. OK, go ahead. Q: Am I there? OK. GOODMAN: Yes, you’re back. Good. Q: Can you hear me? GOODMAN: I can hear you and see your wonderful Zoom picture too, so. Q: OK. I am the city council member here in Pine Bluff, Arkansas.  And let me preface it by saying that the citizens here, there are some citizens here who really do think that the United States need to help more of our Americans before we start giving aid overseas. But overall here, we do believe in aid, foreign aid, because a lot of our citizens here are veterans, and educators, and farmers. And so we do believe in foreign aid, because we do believe that it promotes stability, you know, in regards to addressing poverty and inequality. And that can help us not have a lot of terrorism come our way. You know, it kind of lightens the threat of terrorism. But also economic interest, just being able to foster that economic growth where Americans, we can have our goods also have opportunities to grow into other markets outside the United States. You know, that win-win situation. And then just with the United States being the humanitarian country that we are, you know, being able to help those that are in need gives us a great reputation globally.  And then, in regards to—and I’m trying to go quick because I know everybody else got to speak too, but there’s a lot that I want to say on that. But also, it could build alliances with other nations and countries when we give foreign aid to others. And so just and then—and having that foreign—helping with the foreign aid, and having that camaraderie and that relationship with other countries can also help us nationwide attack a problem that all of us are having, in reference to climate changes, and pandemics, and food insecurities, and anything else that we might be facing that’s not just localized to America, but to everybody globally. So that’s just what I wanted to say.  GOODMAN: OK. So, Lanette, I think that the current administrator—that is, the head of the U.S. Agency for International Development, which is our, you know, government agency that provides bilateral foreign aid, she could not have given a better speech than the one you just gave—about the case for foreign aid, the combination of stability, sort of prosperity, and economic benefit, the humanitarian cause, the diplomatic benefits. I think you’ve perfectly summarized the case for. And you preface it by—you know, by saying that, obviously, people want—you know, want— Q: More aid here. GOODMAN: Well, they want money to be spent at home, too.  Q: Mmm hmm. GOODMAN: So I think that’s understandable. You know, we don’t spend that much on foreign aid. It’s, you know, 1 percent of the national budget. So it’s not nearly as big as people think it is.  Q: It isn’t.  GOODMAN: Right? But it is—but it is a legitimate issue for people to be—to be looking at and questioning. But I think you’ve made a lot of great points there. And that would be exactly what somebody would say about, you know, everything from the Marshall Plan after World War II, when we made that sort of bet that if we reinvested in rebuilding Europe and Japan they would become strong allies, they’d become strong markets, economically they’d be more stable, and so forth. Right up to things like—I often talk about the PEPFAR initiative, the President’s Emergency Plan for AIDS Relief, which President George W. Bush launched twenty years ago in sub-Saharan Africa. And, you know, for a cost of only a few billion, I think, over that twenty years—which, you know, in the scheme of things is not a huge amount of money—we’ve saved something like 25 million lives and created huge, great goodwill in Africa. So, you know, it is a strong thing.  On the other hand, it’s American taxpayer money. And, you know, people are right to question whether this is the best use of that money. So you hear that as well. And I suspect that some of the people who said it harms the U.S.—does anybody else want to jump in on this, especially to make that point about why it’s not a great investment for the U.S.? If not, we can skip on. I know we’re—time is ticking here. So why don’t we go through the next two, and then we’ll—and then we’ll come back and give you a few minutes at the end to intervene on anything you want to talk about.  So, number four: Would you support or oppose the government’s further restricting investment with China? So it looks like a pretty significant majority support that, at least somewhat, if not strongly. For, like, almost 90 percent. So does anybody want to comment on that, either—I was like to take the minority who didn’t make that point. Like, why would you oppose further restricting investment with China? Does anybody want to who—voted that way, that 13 percent, want to raise their hand and explain why they don’t think restricting investment with China is a good thing, or further restricting it? Or on the other side is fine too. Welcome any additional hands. I don’t see any hands yet. There we go. Michael, go ahead. You need to unmute. There we go. Go ahead, Michael. Still can’t hear you. You look like you’re unmuted, but—OK. I’ll tell you what, Michael—are you there? OK. I’m not hearing you. Is anybody else hearing Michael? I think maybe— OPERATOR: I think we’re having problems hearing Michael. But, Michael, I encourage you to use the written Q&A as well if your microphone is not working.  GOODMAN: OK. OK. And I—if anybody else wants to comment on this question about further restricting investment with China? Anybody have any thoughts? Michael, you want to try again? Still not coming through. Anybody else want to jump in on that? OK, Eric. Oh, you got to unmute there. OK.  Q: Can you hear me? GOODMAN: Yes, go ahead.  Q: Sorry. Just in terms of investing in China, it’s already been proven that they’re using the investment to gain intellectual knowledge that they didn’t have before. And I’m all for businesses and countries being able to support themselves, but it shouldn’t be at the detriment of our intellectual property. And so restricting foreign investment in China, it can make some sense. But at the same time it can also do us some harm with the relationship that we have with China as a trading partner. But the trading has been completely in favor of China.  And on that basis, I would probably agree that we should restrict the transfer of intellectual property to China. But at this point, so much of our intellectual property has already been stolen, I don’t know that we could ever recover from it, because they dominate the solar industry, and so many other different industries, and they’re determined to dominate the electric industry as well by flooding our country with so many cheap goods with intellectual property that they may have gained unlawfully, that I just don’t know that we can recover from it. And just in terms of that. So restricting it, yes, I think we should restrict it. GOODMAN: OK. So that’s investment to China. And there is both a concern, you know, here in Washington about investment going in for that reason, intellectual property also, because of the point about concentrating our risks, or, you know, our dependencies. I think you made this point earlier about dependencies in China. And so trying to get countries—companies to pull out. Of course, companies have their own reasons why they’re pulling out of China, because it’s not growing as fast, because it’s a difficult market to be in, in addition to U.S. government policy measures that may be incentivizing that move out of China.  And then there’s also a new set of guidelines on outbound sort of financial investment, like Tom who’s a finance guy would probably know about this. That there’s an effort to restrict financial investment into certain technologies in China, like, you know, advanced AI-related and other high-tech production in China. So there’s a lot of conversation about investment that direction. There’s also investment this direction. And the question about whether there—we ought to be restricting Chinese investment into the United States from China. And I don’t know if anybody has a view on that. I see Alderman Lanette has got her hand up again. Do you want to offer any thoughts on this topic, Lanette? Go ahead. Q: OK. Can you hear me?  GOODMAN: Yes, ma’am.  Q: And, again, I agree with the gentleman that just spoke about the intellectual property. We have to protect it. You know, so limiting Chinese investments can definitely help us in that regard. And then also just thinking about national security on the whole. When it comes to Chinese investments and stuff. We already have seen issues as far as technology and espionage and things like that. So we want to definitely have some kind of control, and some kind of mechanism in place to guarantee—we can’t always 100 percent guarantee national security. But we should come doggone close to it. So we want to be careful of what we do in regards to—in regards to that.  So I just wanted to tap in on the gentleman’s question. I definitely agree with him. And then, just being able to level the playing field. I mean, the Chinese, like we know they have different values and different kinds of thoughts sometimes when it comes to trade and business and things like that that we do. So just being able to level the playing field and stuff. So I think the restrictions definitely need to be in place. I think that we got to be careful when we’re dealing with Chinese—well, anybody, really, outside of the United States. But we definitely know that they are—they can be a potential threat if we don’t be careful. GOODMAN: Great. Well said. OK, great, great points, all of those. Again, thanks, Lanette.  And let me take John Kurtz and then Stephanie Agee. And then we’ll come back to you, Tom, again. But I wanted to get new voices in here. So, John, go ahead and unmute yourself, and then feel free to make your point.  Q: Hi, this is John Kurtz from Buchanan County, Iowa. I’m a county supervisor.  We’re very heavily in the agricultural industry, but we’re also adjacent to two John Deere factories here. And Chinese investment is a frightening thing in our farm economy. They’re buying up land. It’s not just Iowa, it’s South Dakota. There’s a lot of areas that are being invested by China. They’ve also taken over one of the biggest pork producers in the United States, Smithfield Foods. And I’m afraid that if we let China have too much power over there, if we were to get into an armed conflict with them, they could shut us down. And we would really stifle our production at factories and everything else with all the product that is being imported to support those factories. GOODMAN: Right. Good. And that national security point is a particularly important one, and one that obviously gets a lot of conversation here in Washington these days.  Q: Well, remember what happened during COVID when the ports were all backed up and we couldn’t get any product in the United States. And that could very easily happen again.  GOODMAN: Yeah. Yeah. And that’s another problem in the world, another disruptive factor right here around Washington. Here we have this terrible thing with the bridge in Baltimore that’s having a visible effect here on supplies of a lot of things. So good points. Thank you, John. Appreciate that.  Stephanie, do you want to jump in here? Q: Yes. Hi. Can you hear me?  GOODMAN: Hi. Q: Great. Matt, good to see you. Stephanie Agree from the state of Virginia, vice president for— GOODMAN: I remember you. How are you?  Q: Doing great. Doing great. Thank you so much for—to you and CFR for organizing this session. I really appreciate it.  So as my title would suggest, I’m focused on international trade. I’m here for it. I absolutely understand many of the—the impacts that it has had negatively in parts of the country, but I don’t want to ignore the tremendous positive impact it’s had on our country as well, and the world for that matter. Which is also important. Impacting the world and having positive impacts for the world is important. And I think that’s been noted in several different comments here, where people have talked about the importance of U.S. aid and how it’s important for us to have these positive impacts so that we have less unrest in other parts of the world, that the U.S. then has to end up responding to.  But specifically, back to the comments about restrictions on China investment. I answered this—I said, you know, somewhat oppose them. And the way that I was thinking about it was more about restrictions by the United States on companies’ ability to invest in or trade with China. So I probably—I might have answered it slightly differently than others. But I think my point here is my reservations about the government, the U.S. government, limiting the private sector’s ability to make investments and to make decisions. Also noting that there are lots of rules around the exports of products and services that have any impact on national security. The U.S. government is doing a very good job, I feel, at that, and being very protective of those things.  So I just want to note that those restrictions are in place. They certainly impact a lot of my Virginia companies that are trying to export their products, not necessarily to China but to other parts of the world. So if we—if we—if we paint it with a broad brush and say that, you know, limitations on the private sector’s ability to make government—to make their own decisions about where they—who they do business with and how they do business, that’s really where my—kind of where my opposition lies.  GOODMAN: Right. Got it. Those are really good points, Stephanie. And, you know, traditionally in the investment policy world there’s been a concept of the negative list approach, which means things that you feel for national security reasons or other reasons you don’t want, you know, foreign investment into your country. And that’s a legitimate issue for every country. That you put them on a negative list, and you say: You cannot do these things. But if it isn’t on that list, then it—you know, it’s open and it’s possible to do investment and have the benefits of that cross-border flow, and the private sector dynamic that you discussed. That’s been the traditional approach to investment policy. We tried to get China to move to that approach too, by the way, a more negative list approach. But these days, there’s more talk about broader sets of restrictions and arguments in favor of a new approach here. But there is a cost.  By the way, I didn’t say at the beginning, we have a—sort of a branded platform as part of RealEcon called Trade-Offs. And we’re writing essays. And we might also do debates or other things over time to talk about the trade-offs. Any one of these policies that we’ve been talking about, there’s some good things, some bad things. So it’s, like, there’s no—very few things in life, probably, but also in this area of international economics, are absolute. It’s sort of there’s some positive, some negative. And either choice might be legitimate, but there’s usually a cost of some kind. And so the question is, you have to decide which—you know, how much cost are you willing to pay for some other benefit? You know, that’s part of—it is intrinsic to—it's really at the heart of a lot of the stuff we’re looking at here. So stay tuned for more trade-offs conversations.  OK, Tom, you’ve been patient. And then I’m going to just give you—if you can be as concise as you can. And then I’d want to just get to this last question, then give anybody any further chances to jump in on any of this. Go ahead, Tom. You’ll need to unmute there. There you go. Q: There it went. It finally went. I was clicking on it several times and it finally took. On the foreign aid issue, I am for targeted foreign aid. I believe most people here are. You do have to screen it carefully to make sure you are getting value for what you’re doing and it’s not just indiscriminate, giving the taxpayers’ money away to—because people are very sensitive to that. Like, there’s a lot of places with needs. And a lot of it’s because of upheavals or refugee status, or whatever in the world that we really need to help them. I was just reading the Financial Times today about the Solomon Islands just electing a prime minister who is pro-China friendly. And the U.S. evidently over the past number of years has not been, let’s say, trying to give them the warm and fuzzy. And the Chinese have made great inroads there.  And so that’s—you know, you have to pay attention to that and that take your eye off the ball. But, again, when it comes to trade, my real beef is with China. And it’s because its authoritarian regime, all the businesses, basically, are—even the private business, technically, have to kowtow to whatever the regime says. And once the current leader came in place a number of years ago, they took a real hard tack in a different direction from where they’d been going for twenty-odd years. You know, they’ve gone back to really centralizing everything and to trying to be extremely outwardly aggressive. And it is unfortunate. GOODMAN: Yeah. Yeah, no, under this president— Q: And the initial intent of going—working with China was to improve them and improve the world and make them a better place and more agreeable and/or a country that could easily assimilate into the world, if you know what I’m saying. And it’s having a total turn. And it’s become very, very authoritarian. And when you combine authoritarianism with the power they had developed under the more liberal policies, and convert that one way, it is very dangerous for the world and extremely impossible to compete with. And given they’ve turned so authoritarian—I mean, they’re a virtual police state over there. And nothing gets done unless the government wants it done. And this may sound hard and crass, but they have almost become what I would call the new Nazi, Germany, when it comes to a business model. And they’re a police state. And it’s very difficult to deal with something like that. And feeding that monster isn’t going to help us. It’ll never, never help us. So it sounds hard, but I look at it. It’s a police state. Government control. And they wield a lot of power. But people still say, I can make money—free enterprise. I can make money off of trading with them. So to me, it’s a dangerous game. It’s a dangerous game we’re in right now. And I wish the leadership would change and become more moderate, obviously, but— GOODMAN: Yeah. I think no question under Xi Jinping, the current president who took over in 2012-2013, there has been that shift, as you mentioned, very sharply. And it’s very problematic for us and, I think, actually for them too. I think long term it’s not good for them. And but, yeah, there was, you know, twenty years ago a sort of different leadership that had, I think, a different approach to reform. And that I think was genuine. I think they were trying to move in a different direction. But that’s the China we’re dealing with today. So those are good points.  Let me—let me just ask—I see that—I see that we’ve got a comment in the—in the chat from Greg. I don’t know if you want to make that point to the group by raising your hand or just speaking. That’d be great. And meanwhile—OK, you got your hand up. Go ahead, Greg. If you can introduce yourself. You’ll need to unmute there. Yeah. Can’t hear you yet, Greg. But if you could try to unmute one more time. And then if not, I can read your question, and your point quickly here. OK. Don’t think we’re getting you here. So yeah.  No, the point you’re making is about electric vehicles. And China’s advancing and making actually, frankly, quite good electric vehicles now. Whatever you think of how they got the technology or whatever, the reality is they are producing electric cars that are pretty good and are cheaper than Teslas and things. And I drove one of these in Europe last summer when we just happened to rent a car and it was one of these BYD Chinese cars. And it’s not bad, actually. So and it helps address climate change, as you make in your point, but it also—because they’re making these things with huge subsidies and undercutting producers here and in Europe and so forth, it’s creating a backlash and a concern about whether we’re going to be able to produce these things ourselves, or sustain it.  So let me just quickly for—great point. And just before, John, you get on there, just thirty seconds. Does anybody have anything to say about the climate change point? I guess, in a way, Greg was just getting to that by talking about electric vehicles. Anybody want to say—is that the point you wanted to address, John, or was it something else? John Kurtz. Go ahead. Q: Yes. I wanted to comment on the climate change issue. No matter what we do in the United States, until India and China do something it—we’ve already made huge strides in the United States. And right now, in Iowa, South Dakota, North Dakota, we’re being pressured put in this CO2 sequestration plan to capture CO2 from our ethanol plants. And it’s crazy. I mean, CO2 is what fuels plants to live. And here, we’re making this big push to capture all the CO2. What’s that going to do to our farming economy? Trees, everything—we all learned it in school. That’s the only way they survive, they produce oxygen from CO2. And our farm community is very, very concerned about it. GOODMAN: Good. And that is a strong argument on the side of, you know, of concern about some of these efforts to address climate change. On the other hand, you know, there’s an argument that’s pretty powerful that this is a—you know, becoming a planetary problem that is going to cause all kinds of other, you know, disruptions to our economic capabilities. And certainly, the Biden administration feels pretty strongly about that, and has invested $370 billion or something through the Inflation Reduction Act in climate and clean energy solutions.  And some of that’s providing economic benefit in your states, I can imagine. I wish I could explore this really important topic more thoroughly, but we’re already past time and there’s a hard rule at CFR not to go over time, which I apologize for having done. Let me just thank everybody for great comments and input. Not enough time. It’d be great to do this again. And I hope to do it in person. Certainly, if you come to Washington please swing by CFR. We’d love to hear more, have more conversation with you. In the meantime, thanks a lot, everybody. And back to you, Irina. FASKIANOS: Thank you so much, Matt. Really appreciate you doing this, and to all of you for your comments. We will send out a link to the webinar recording and transcript, along with contact information for Matt if you want to follow up with him, and if you want to invite him to your state for—to show him what’s happening in your communities. I’m just offering you up there, Matt.  And to learn more about CFR’s RealEcon Initiative, you should go to CFR.org/initiative/RealEcon, which we put in the chat window and we will also include in our follow-up note to all of you. And, as always, we encourage you to go to CFR.org. ForeignAffairs.com, and ThinkGlobalHealth.org for the latest developments and analysis on international trends and how they are affecting the United States. Of course, please do share your thoughts for speakers and topics for future webinars. You can email [email protected]. Again, thank you for all that you do in your communities. And we look forward to continuing the dialogue. Enjoy the rest of your day. END
  • Europe
    A Conversation With Christine Lagarde
    Play
    European Central Bank President Christine Lagarde discusses the state of the European economy, U.S.-EU economic cooperation, and the implications of international geopolitical conflicts on the global economy. This meeting is held in collaboration with the Peterson Institute for International Economics. The C. Peter McColough Series on International Economics brings the world's foremost economic policymakers and scholars to address members on current topics in international economics and U.S. monetary policy. This meeting series is presented by the Greenberg Center for Geoeconomic Studies.
  • Economics
    Local Leaders in the Global Economy
    Podcast
    Many Americans are losing faith in the benefits of internationalism. But whether it’s wars in the Gaza Strip and Ukraine, worsening extreme weather as a result of climate change, or the trade-offs of globalization, events abroad are increasingly having a local impact. At the same time, more state and local officials in the United States are becoming involved in global affairs, conducting their own form of diplomacy on international issues and driving investment home. What role should the United States play in the world economy? And how do states and cities fit in?
  • Japan
    The Japanese Bid for Foreign Bonds After the End of Yield Curve Control
    The Bank of Japan (BoJ) is widely expected to end yield curve control. But Japanese yields will remain low, and foreign bonds will remain attractive to those Japanese investors who don’t have to hedge.
  • China
    China’s New Currency Playbook
    China’s pivot to a new strategy of indirect intervention through its large state banks requires new approaches to policing currency policies by both the U.S. Treasury and IMF.